Everyone knows that artificial intelligence (AI) is a hugely powerful technology with immense economic implications. US equity prices reflect not only confidence in the prospects of technology companies, but also a belief that AI would fuel a broader boom. The growth-obsessed British government views AI development as a top priority, and everyone at the World Economic Forum in Davos in January wanted to hear from the world’s AI leaders.
We have been here before. In the 1960s, computers were too enormous and expensive to be used by anyone but the largest government agencies and businesses. Yet so great were concerns about “automation” that former US president Lyndon Johnson launched an inquiry into the danger that computer-based technologies might “eliminate all but a few jobs.” It was not to be. By the 1970s, there was no sign of a productivity surge and fears of mass technological unemployment subsided.
Personal and business computer use then soared in the 1980s; but by 1990, as the economist Robert Solow said, information technology (IT) was “everywhere but in the productivity statistics.” With mobile phones, the Internet, ever-expanding hardware capacity and growing software capabilities promising a new connectivity-based productivity revolution, everyone at the World Economic Forum in 2000 wanted to hear from the leaders of information and communications technology (ICT).
Cisco CEO John Chambers predicted that ICT would enable the US economy to grow by 5 percent per year for the foreseeable future, and that “the Internet will form half of gross domestic product by 2010.”
Then there was “big data,” “the digital economy,” “machine learning” and now AI. None, so far, has had any measurable impact on medium-term growth rates. A case can be made that generative AI, owing to its self-learning capability, represents more than just another stage of technological development. However, there are still two reasons why it, too, might not show up in growth data.
First, a large and probably growing share of economic activity involves a zero-sum struggle for competitive advantage with no positive impact on either measured growth or human welfare. Using basic Internet search, and now sophisticated large language models, lawyers are increasingly able to analyze every possible precedent before presenting their arguments. However, if the opposing law firm can do the same, the result is an arms race in which neither party has a durable advantage.
For at least two decades, experts have warned that after the steady decline of manufacturing jobs, professional services such as the law would be next in line for automation. However, employment and pay in the field of commercial law continue to grow.
Similarly, marketing departments can use AI to produce ever more targeted and effective communications to influence consumer choice. However, if their competitors are doing the same, there is no benefit to end consumers and no boost to GDP.
Conversely, AI would almost certainly deliver huge human welfare benefits almost for free. The late economist Martin Feldstein in 2017 correctly observed that phenomenon at work in the previous three decades of remarkable IT and ICT progress. By then, smartphones boasted many thousands of times more processing power and memory than the biggest computers of the 1960s, enabling vastly more communication, data storage, video and image sharing, and so forth. Yet the share of GDP accounted for by the telecoms sector had hardly changed, leading Feldstein to conclude that “low growth estimates fail to reflect the remarkable innovations in everything from healthcare to Internet services to video entertainment that have made life better during these years.”
Likewise, Google DeepMind’s AlphaFold Protein Structure Database (which predicts a protein structure from its amino acid sequence) is set to accelerate drug discovery while slashing the cost of research. However, once drugs come off patent, their prices fall toward their marginal cost of production and their contribution to measured GDP collapses.
If, by 2070, an AI-enabled acceleration of knowledge acquisition has furnished us with a wonder drug that gives everyone a 100-year life of perfect health, and which is produced in wholly automated factories powered by cheap nuclear fusion, it would count for almost nothing in global GDP. The more powerful a technology, the more rapidly it disappears from measured GDP.
At the same time, AI would have massive potential to exacerbate the harms to human welfare that previous generations of ICT have already produced. Deepfake capabilities are already driving an explosion of online scams, and AI-powered social media algorithms are deepening political polarization and probably contributing to what social psychologist Jonathan Haidt sees as an epidemic of mental illness among young people. Yet none of those negatives show up in measured GDP, either.
For good or ill — or merely as an enabler of ever more intense zero-sum competition — AI would have a pervasive and perhaps transformative impact on society. However, the hope that it would unleash a sustained increase in measured productivity and GDP growth is probably a delusion.
Adair Turner, chair of the Energy Transitions Commission, was chair of the UK Financial Services Authority from 2008 to 2012. He is the author of many books, including Between Debt and the Devil: Money, Credit, and Fixing Global Finance.
Copyright: Project Syndicate
Having lived through former British prime minister Boris Johnson’s tumultuous and scandal-ridden administration, the last place I had expected to come face-to-face with “Mr Brexit” was in a hotel ballroom in Taipei. Should I have been so surprised? Over the past few years, Taiwan has unfortunately become the destination of choice for washed-up Western politicians to turn up long after their political careers have ended, making grandiose speeches in exchange for extraordinarily large paychecks far exceeding the annual salary of all but the wealthiest of Taiwan’s business tycoons. Taiwan’s pursuit of bygone politicians with little to no influence in their home
In a recent essay, “How Taiwan Lost Trump,” a former adviser to US President Donald Trump, Christian Whiton, accuses Taiwan of diplomatic incompetence — claiming Taipei failed to reach out to Trump, botched trade negotiations and mishandled its defense posture. Whiton’s narrative overlooks a fundamental truth: Taiwan was never in a position to “win” Trump’s favor in the first place. The playing field was asymmetrical from the outset, dominated by a transactional US president on one side and the looming threat of Chinese coercion on the other. From the outset of his second term, which began in January, Trump reaffirmed his
It is difficult not to agree with a few points stated by Christian Whiton in his article, “How Taiwan Lost Trump,” and yet the main idea is flawed. I am a Polish journalist who considers Taiwan her second home. I am conservative, and I might disagree with some social changes being promoted in Taiwan right now, especially the push for progressiveness backed by leftists from the West — we need to clean up our mess before blaming the Taiwanese. However, I would never think that those issues should dominate the West’s judgement of Taiwan’s geopolitical importance. The question is not whether
In 2025, it is easy to believe that Taiwan has always played a central role in various assessments of global national interests. But that is a mistaken belief. Taiwan’s position in the world and the international support it presently enjoys are relatively new and remain highly vulnerable to challenges from China. In the early 2000s, the George W. Bush Administration had plans to elevate bilateral relations and to boost Taiwan’s defense. It designated Taiwan as a non-NATO ally, and in 2001 made available to Taiwan a significant package of arms to enhance the island’s defenses including the submarines it long sought.