A global controversy is raging: What new regulations are required to restore confidence in the financial system and ensure that a new crisis does not erupt a few years down the line.
Bank of England Governor Mervyn King has called for restrictions on the kinds of activities in which mega-banks can engage. British Prime Minister Gordon Brown begs to differ: After all, the first British bank to fall — at a cost of some US$50 billion — was Northern Rock, which was engaged in the “plain vanilla” business of mortgage lending.
The implication of Brown’s observation is that such restrictions will not ensure that there is not another crisis; but King is right to demand that banks that are too big to fail be reined in. In the US, the UK and elsewhere, large banks have been responsible for the bulk of the cost to taxpayers. The US has let 106 smaller banks go bankrupt this year alone. It’s the mega-banks that present the mega-costs.
The crisis is a result of at least eight distinct but related failures.
Too-big-to-fail banks have perverse incentives: If they gamble and win, they walk off with the proceeds; if they fail, taxpayers pick up the tab.
Financial institutions are too intertwined to fail: The part of American Insurance Group that cost US taxpayers US$180 billion was relatively small.
Even if individual banks are small, if they engage in correlated behavior — using the same models — their behavior can fuel systemic risk.
Incentive structures within banks are designed to encourage short-sighted behavior and excessive risk taking.
In assessing their own risk, banks do not look at the externalities that they (or their failure) would impose on others, which is one reason why we need regulation in the first place.
Banks have done a bad job in risk assessment — the models they were using were deeply flawed.
Investors, seemingly even less informed about the risk of excessive leverage than banks, put enormous pressure on banks to undertake excessive risk.
Regulators, who are supposed to understand all of this and prevent actions that spur systemic risk, failed. They too used flawed models and had flawed incentives — too many didn’t understand the role of regulation and too many became “captured” by those they were supposed to be regulating.
If we could have more confidence in our regulators and supervisors, we might be more relaxed about all the other problems. However, regulators and supervisors are fallible, which is why we need to attack the problems from all sides.
There are, of course, costs to regulations, but the costs of having an inadequate regulatory structure are enormous. We have not done nearly enough to prevent another crisis and the benefits of strengthened regulation far outweigh any increased costs.
King is right: Banks that are too big to fail are too big to exist. If they continue to exist, they must exist in what is sometimes called a “utility” model, meaning that they are heavily regulated.
In particular, allowing such banks to continue engaging in proprietary trading distorts financial markets. Why should they be allowed to gamble with taxpayers underwriting their losses? What are the “synergies”? Can they possibly outweigh the costs? Some large banks are now involved in a sufficiently large share of trading (either on their own account or on behalf of their customers) that they have, in effect, gained the same unfair advantage that any inside trader has.
This may generate higher profits for them, but at the expense of others. It is a skewed playing field — and one increasingly skewed against smaller players. Who wouldn’t prefer a credit default swap underwritten by the US or UK government; no wonder that too-big-to-fail institutions dominate this market.
The one thing nowadays that economists agree upon is that incentives matter. Bank officers got rewarded for higher returns — whether they were a result of improved performance (doing better than the market) or just more risk taking (higher leverage).
Either they were swindling shareholders and investors, or they didn’t understand the nature of risk and reward. Possibly both are true. Either way, it’s discouraging.
Given the lack of understanding of risk by investors and deficiencies in corporate governance, bankers had an incentive not to design good incentive structures. It is vital to correct such flaws — at the level of the organization and of the individual manager.
That means breaking up too-important-to fail (or too-complex-to-fix) institutions. Where this is not possible, it means stringently restricting what they can do and imposing higher taxes and capital-adequacy requirements, thereby helping level the playing field. The devil, of course, is in the details — and big banks will do what they can to ensure that whatever charges are imposed are sufficiently small that they do not outweigh the advantages gained from being underwritten by taxpayers.
Even if we fix bank incentive structures perfectly — which is not in the cards — the banks will still represent a big risk. The bigger the bank and the more risk-taking in which big banks are allowed to engage, the greater the threat to our economies and our societies.
These are not matters of black and white: The more we limit the size, the more relaxed we can be about these and other details of regulation. That is why King, Paul Volcker, the UN Commission of Experts on Reforms of the International Monetary and Financial System and a host of others are right about the need to curb the big banks. What is required is a multi-prong approach, including special taxes, increased capital requirements, tighter supervision and limits on size and risk-taking activities.
Such an approach won’t prevent another crisis, but it would make one less likely — and less costly if it did occur.
Joseph Stiglitz is University Professor at Columbia University and the winner of the 2001 Nobel Prize in economics.
COPYRIGHT: PROJECT SYNDICATE
China has not been a top-tier issue for much of the second Trump administration. Instead, Trump has focused considerable energy on Ukraine, Israel, Iran, and defending America’s borders. At home, Trump has been busy passing an overhaul to America’s tax system, deporting unlawful immigrants, and targeting his political enemies. More recently, he has been consumed by the fallout of a political scandal involving his past relationship with a disgraced sex offender. When the administration has focused on China, there has not been a consistent throughline in its approach or its public statements. This lack of overarching narrative likely reflects a combination
Father’s Day, as celebrated around the world, has its roots in the early 20th century US. In 1910, the state of Washington marked the world’s first official Father’s Day. Later, in 1972, then-US president Richard Nixon signed a proclamation establishing the third Sunday of June as a national holiday honoring fathers. Many countries have since followed suit, adopting the same date. In Taiwan, the celebration takes a different form — both in timing and meaning. Taiwan’s Father’s Day falls on Aug. 8, a date chosen not for historical events, but for the beauty of language. In Mandarin, “eight eight” is pronounced
US President Donald Trump’s alleged request that Taiwanese President William Lai (賴清德) not stop in New York while traveling to three of Taiwan’s diplomatic allies, after his administration also rescheduled a visit to Washington by the minister of national defense, sets an unwise precedent and risks locking the US into a trajectory of either direct conflict with the People’s Republic of China (PRC) or capitulation to it over Taiwan. Taiwanese authorities have said that no plans to request a stopover in the US had been submitted to Washington, but Trump shared a direct call with Chinese President Xi Jinping (習近平)
It is difficult to think of an issue that has monopolized political commentary as intensely as the recall movement and the autopsy of the July 26 failures. These commentaries have come from diverse sources within Taiwan and abroad, from local Taiwanese members of the public and academics, foreign academics resident in Taiwan, and overseas Taiwanese working in US universities. There is a lack of consensus that Taiwan’s democracy is either dying in ashes or has become a phoenix rising from the ashes, nurtured into existence by civic groups and rational voters. There are narratives of extreme polarization and an alarming