This summer, California’s water authority declared that wasting water — hosing a sidewalk, for example — was a crime. Next door, in Nevada, Las Vegas has paid out US$200 million over the past decade for homes and businesses to replace their lawns with xeriscaped yards.
It is set to get worse. As climate change and population growth further stress the US water supply from the drought-plagued west to the seemingly bottomless Great Lakes, states and municipalities are likely to impose increasingly draconian restrictions on water use.
Such efforts might be more effective than simply exhorting people to conserve. In August, for example, cities and towns in California consumed much less water — 10.22 billion liters less — than in August last year.
Illustration: June Hsu
However, the proliferation of limits on water use is unlikely to solve the problem, because regulations do nothing to address the main driver of the nation’s wanton consumption of water: price.
“Most water problems are readily addressed with innovation,” David Victor of the University of California, San Diego said. “Getting the water price right to signal scarcity is crucially important.”
The signals today are way off. Water is far too cheap across most US cities and towns. However, worse is the way that the US quenches the thirst of farmers, who account for 80 percent of the nation’s water consumption and for whom water costs virtually nothing.
Adding to the challenges are the obstacles placed in the way of water trading.
“Markets are essential to ensuring that water, when it is scarce, can go to the most valuable uses,” Stanford Law School environmental resources expert Barton Thompson said. Without them, “the allocation of water is certainly arbitrary.”
Two studies to be presented at a forum tomorrow organized by the Hamilton Project at the Brookings Institution and the Stanford Woods Institute for the Environment make the case that markets and prices are an indispensable part of the toolkit to combat water scarcity. They are essential to induce conservation and investment in water-saving technology, and to steer water to where it is valued most.
“There is enough water; we can live within our means, but the systems we have in place simply do not have enough flexibility to move water to the places where it is most needed,” Denver Water chief executive officer Jim Lochhead said.
The price of water going into US homes often does not even cover the cost of delivering it, let alone the depreciation of utilities’ infrastructure or their R&D. It certainly does not account for other costs imposed by water use — on, say, fisheries or the environment — caused by taking water out of rivers or lakes.
Consumers have little incentive to conserve. Despite California’s distress, about half of the homes in the capital, Sacramento, still lack water meters, paying a flat fee no matter how much water they consume.
Some utilities do worse, by charging decreasing rates the more water is consumed. Utilities, of course, have little incentive to discourage consumption: The more they did that the more their revenues would decline.
Rates have little relation to water’s replacement cost. In Fresno, California, which gets less than 279.4mm of rain a year, a family of four using 400 gallons (1,514 liters) of water a day faces a monthly bill of US$28.26. In Boston, where rainfall exceeds 1,000mm, the same family would pay US$77.73.
While this might seem a mess, it is nothing compared to the incentives available to US agriculture.
Farmers water rights are primarily subject to state law. In the west, they have been allocated by a method that closely resembles “first come, first served.” The first farm that drew water had a right to whatever it needed pretty much forever. Junior users — who arrived later — had to stand in line.
Farmers pay if the government brings the water to the farm, say via an aqueduct from the Colorado River. However, the fees are minimal. Farmers in California’s Imperial Irrigation District pay US$20 per acre-foot (1.23 million liters), less than a tenth of what it can cost in San Diego. In addition, the government has often subsidized farmers via things like interest-free loans to cover upfront investments. An acre-foot is the amount it takes to cover 1 acre (0.4 hectares) of land a foot deep in water.
This kind of arrangement helps explain why about half the 60 million acres of irrigated land in the US use flood irrigation — just flooding the fields with water — which is about as wasteful a method as there is. It also helps explain why underground water reserves declined by 53 million acre-feet between 2003 and this year, about twice the volume of Lake Mead.
This is hardly the only obstacle to conservation. A farm that does not use its full allotment of water risks forfeiting it for not putting it to “beneficial use.” Any water saved automatically flows to other farmers with junior rights.
Farmers in many states are theoretically allowed to lease unused water. However, the many holders of junior rights can block them, and they are legion: California has granted rights equal to five times its average annual flow of surface water.
These restrictions have perverse consequences. San Diego, for instance, is building the nation’s biggest desalination plant to produce fresh water at a cost of about US$2,000 per acre-foot. Yet alfalfa growers in Southern California last year used hundreds of millions of liters growing alfalfa that might fetch at best US$340 a ton (907.18kg), or US$920 per acre-foot of water.
Markets and sensible pricing structures are good at resolving these types of problems. Some water districts, like Irvine Ranch in Orange County, California, have introduced rising fee schedules that start low for a basic allotment covering families’ essential needs and rise quickly with volume to make people think twice about refilling the swimming pool.
Spurred by the sense of crisis, incipient water markets show great promise. Santa Fe, New Mexico, has required builders to have water rights with their building applications since 2005 — giving farmers an opportunity to sell their rights to developers rather than using them for low-value crops.
In 2003, the San Diego Water Authority cut a deal with the Imperial Irrigation District — a large area of parched farmland near California’s border with Arizona — to provide the city with 200,000 acre-feet of water at a price starting at US$258 per acre-foot.
Seven states in the Colorado River system are starting a pilot program to explore a market linking farmers and urban water districts to maintain water volumes in Lake Powell and Lake Mead.
This is not quite charging farmers for the water they use. That might be a bridge too far, considering the tight margins of many farms and the political clout of many farmers.
Still, markets such as those timidly emerging in the west could not only free water for the users who value it more, but they could also provide farmers with the revenue needed to invest in water management technology.
None of this is going to come easily. People like cheap water and protest when rates rise. Farmers have resisted transfers of water to cities at least since California’s water wars a century ago.
However, the looming prospect of acute water scarcity demands a solution. It is not only the west’s problem. Two years ago, the drought in the Midwest was as severe as the drought in California. Lakes Michigan, Superior and Huron were at historic lows.
Alternative solutions have been proposed — like towing icebergs from the Arctic or diverting water from the Missouri River to use on the other side of the Rockies. However, the standard response to scarcity — grabbing more — cannot work any longer. There is not more water to grab.
Which means markets must play their part.
“Without prices or trade, we will just get more diversion of rivers, more dams and more wells,” and nothing will be fixed, said Robert Glennon, an expert on water at Arizona University’s College of Law.
US President Donald Trump and Chinese President Xi Jinping (習近平) were born under the sign of Gemini. Geminis are known for their intelligence, creativity, adaptability and flexibility. It is unlikely, then, that the trade conflict between the US and China would escalate into a catastrophic collision. It is more probable that both sides would seek a way to de-escalate, paving the way for a Trump-Xi summit that allows the global economy some breathing room. Practically speaking, China and the US have vulnerabilities, and a prolonged trade war would be damaging for both. In the US, the electoral system means that public opinion
They did it again. For the whole world to see: an image of a Taiwan flag crushed by an industrial press, and the horrifying warning that “it’s closer than you think.” All with the seal of authenticity that only a reputable international media outlet can give. The Economist turned what looks like a pastiche of a poster for a grim horror movie into a truth everyone can digest, accept, and use to support exactly the opinion China wants you to have: It is over and done, Taiwan is doomed. Four years after inaccurately naming Taiwan the most dangerous place on
In their recent op-ed “Trump Should Rein In Taiwan” in Foreign Policy magazine, Christopher Chivvis and Stephen Wertheim argued that the US should pressure President William Lai (賴清德) to “tone it down” to de-escalate tensions in the Taiwan Strait — as if Taiwan’s words are more of a threat to peace than Beijing’s actions. It is an old argument dressed up in new concern: that Washington must rein in Taipei to avoid war. However, this narrative gets it backward. Taiwan is not the problem; China is. Calls for a so-called “grand bargain” with Beijing — where the US pressures Taiwan into concessions
The term “assassin’s mace” originates from Chinese folklore, describing a concealed weapon used by a weaker hero to defeat a stronger adversary with an unexpected strike. In more general military parlance, the concept refers to an asymmetric capability that targets a critical vulnerability of an adversary. China has found its modern equivalent of the assassin’s mace with its high-altitude electromagnetic pulse (HEMP) weapons, which are nuclear warheads detonated at a high altitude, emitting intense electromagnetic radiation capable of disabling and destroying electronics. An assassin’s mace weapon possesses two essential characteristics: strategic surprise and the ability to neutralize a core dependency.