These days the chairman of US President George W. Bush's Council of Economic Advisers, Ben Bernanke, likes to talk about a "global savings glut" that has produced astonishingly low real interest rates around the world. But that is the wrong way to look at it.
The US certainly does not have a savings glut. Its savings rate has been distressingly low for decades. Then the Bush administration's reckless fiscal policy pushed it lower. Falling interest rates in recent years pushed up real-estate prices and allowed the US' upper middle class to treat their houses as enormous ATM's, lowering savings still more. The US has a savings deficiency, not a glut.
And the rest of the world? A global savings glut would suggest that rebalancing the world economy requires policies to boost America's savings rate and to increase non-US households' consumption. But what the world economy is facing is not a savings glut, but an investment deficiency.
Divide the world into three zones: the US, China, and all the rest. Since the mid-1990s, the net current-account surplus of "all the rest" has risen by an amount that one Federal Reserve Bank economist has put at US$450 billion a year, not because savings rates have increased, but because investment rates have fallen.
Declining investment rates in Japan, the newly industrializing Asian economies, and Latin America, in that order of importance, have fueled the flood of savings into US government bonds, US mortgage-backed securities and US equity-backed loans -- the capital-account equivalent of the US' enormous trade deficit.
The investment deficiency in Asia relative to rates of a decade ago amounts to an annual shortfall of US$400 billion a year, with the decline in investment in Japan -- a consequence of more than a decade of economic stagnation -- accounting for more than half of the total. Moreover, investment rates in the newly industrialized economies of Asia have never recovered to their pre-1997 to 1998 crisis levels, and investment rates in the rest of Asia outside China have fallen off as well. This would seem to call for a very different set of policies to rebalance the world economy.
Yes, the US needs tax increases to move the federal budget into surplus and policies to boost private savings. But the world also needs policies to boost investment in Asia, Latin America, the Middle East and Africa.
And here we face a difficulty. People like me who have been cheerleaders for international integration in trade and finance, as well as for reductions in tariffs and other barriers, have cited three benefits: Maximizing economic -- and also social and cultural -- contact between rich and poor nations is the best way we can think of to aid the flow of knowledge about technology and organization, which is the last best hope for rapid world development.
Lower trade barriers will make locating production in the poor low-wage parts of the world irresistible to those who have access to finance.
Freer capital flows will give poor countries precisely this access, as the greed of investors in rich country leads them to venture into poor regions where capital is scarce.
The first reason still holds true. Maximizing economic, social, and cultural contact between rich and poor remains both the best way to aid the flow of knowledge and the last best hope for rapid world development. But the second and third reasons look shaky. Those with access to finance appear to be capable of resisting the urge to locate production in poor low-wage parts of the world (China aside).
Rather than leading rich-country savers to invest their money in poor countries out of greed, liberalization of capital flows has led poor-country savers to park their money in rich countries out of fear -- fear of political instability, macreconomic disturbances and deficient institutions, especially those that protect the rights of bondholders and minority shareholders.
Something may well happen in the next several years to radically boost the US' savings rate by making American households feel suddenly poor: tax increases, a real-estate crash, rapidly rising import prices caused by a plummeting dollar, a deep recession, or more than one of the above.
It would be nice to believe that when the tide of dollar-denominated securities ebbs, the flows of finance currently directed at the US will smoothly shift course and boost investment in Asia.
But don't count on it, especially considering the share of marginal investment in Asia that is aimed, one way or another, at exporting to the US market. Those outside America, especially in Asia, should regard the unstable state of the US macro-economy with grave concern.
As the seventeenth-century poet John Donne put it, "Ask not for whom the bell tolls -- it tolls for thee."
J. Bradford DeLong, professor of economics at the University of California at Berkeley, was assistant US treasury secretary during the Clinton administration.
copyright: project syndicate
Chinese actor Alan Yu (于朦朧) died after allegedly falling from a building in Beijing on Sept. 11. The actor’s mysterious death was tightly censored on Chinese social media, with discussions and doubts about the incident quickly erased. Even Hong Kong artist Daniel Chan’s (陳曉東) post questioning the truth about the case was automatically deleted, sparking concern among overseas Chinese-speaking communities about the dark culture and severe censorship in China’s entertainment industry. Yu had been under house arrest for days, and forced to drink with the rich and powerful before he died, reports said. He lost his life in this vicious
A recent trio of opinion articles in this newspaper reflects the growing anxiety surrounding Washington’s reported request for Taiwan to shift up to 50 percent of its semiconductor production abroad — a process likely to take 10 years, even under the most serious and coordinated effort. Simon H. Tang (湯先鈍) issued a sharp warning (“US trade threatens silicon shield,” Oct. 4, page 8), calling the move a threat to Taiwan’s “silicon shield,” which he argues deters aggression by making Taiwan indispensable. On the same day, Hsiao Hsi-huei (蕭錫惠) (“Responding to US semiconductor policy shift,” Oct. 4, page 8) focused on
George Santayana wrote: “Those who cannot remember the past are condemned to repeat it.” This article will help readers avoid repeating mistakes by examining four examples from the civil war between the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) forces and the Republic of China (ROC) forces that involved two city sieges and two island invasions. The city sieges compared are Changchun (May to October 1948) and Beiping (November 1948 to January 1949, renamed Beijing after its capture), and attempts to invade Kinmen (October 1949) and Hainan (April 1950). Comparing and contrasting these examples, we can learn how Taiwan may prevent a war with
In South Korea, the medical cosmetic industry is fiercely competitive and prices are low, attracting beauty enthusiasts from Taiwan. However, basic medical risks are often overlooked. While sharing a meal with friends recently, I heard one mention that his daughter would be going to South Korea for a cosmetic skincare procedure. I felt a twinge of unease at the time, but seeing as it was just a casual conversation among friends, I simply reminded him to prioritize safety. I never thought that, not long after, I would actually encounter a patient in my clinic with a similar situation. She had