For an enterprising politician, perhaps the easiest political strategy nowadays is to tell unhappy voters that they are victims — of the biased policies of incumbent elites, of the schemes of other groups, of cunning foreigners. This is especially true when the unhappy group is a distinctive and usually large segment of the voting population and when those being blamed either do not vote or constitute a small share of the electorate. As long as someone else can be blamed, the enterprising politician need not demand anything from unhappy voters; simply promising an end to their victimization will be enough.
Yet, as American essayist H.L. Mencken famously quipped, “for every complex problem, there is an answer that is clear, simple and wrong.” In most cases, the victimhood argument fits this description, which helps to explain why supposed fixes often make things worse.
For example, in many growing Indian cities today, local politicians are proposing minimum employment quotas for the locally born, arguing that too many of the new, high-quality private-sector jobs are going to migrants from other parts of the country. What they fail to see is the vibrant local conditions that have attracted the best and the brightest from elsewhere.
Illustration: Kevin Sheu
The fact that immigrants fill more of the quality jobs need not be, and is most likely not, the result of discrimination; it might simply reflect their greater merit.
Nonetheless, say the politician institutes a minimum quota for locals in higher positions. If the policy is not too onerous, it might well do some good, because locals in higher job positions will offer guidance, mentorship and networks to their fellow locals who are starting out, as every affinity group does.
However, ambitious politicians are rarely satisfied with moderate measures. They want large quotas.
This is where problems emerge. Filling a firm’s upper echelons with sub-par locals affects productivity and competitiveness. This might not matter much if a firm’s competition is confined to the local area, where other firms are subject to the same quota, but it certainly does matter if the firm is competing with firms in other vibrant Indian cities that have refrained from establishing quotas, or with foreign producers. Ultimately, the firm’s growth will suffer, it will hire fewer workers across the board, including local ones, and it might even shift operations to more business-friendly cities.
The upshot is that very competent migrants make local firms competitive, thereby ensuring more jobs — even if not at the highest level — for locals. Vilifying them might seem like an easy political strategy; but acting on it could make conditions significantly worse for one’s constituents.
Similarly, in the US, some politicians claim that deserving native-born students are being kept out of top universities. For his part, US President Donald Trump thinks top universities “should have a cap of maybe around 15 percent, not 31 percent” of foreign students.
However, if foreign students are being selected purely on the basis of merit (and there is little reason to dispute this), a cap would almost certainly reduce the average quality of the student body. This would make US universities less attractive to top students from around the world, who would make it despite the cap, reducing quality further. And with fewer top foreign students staying on to teach and conduct research, the quality of US universities will deteriorate further.
Such a policy therefore could do lasting harm. The US’ universities have long produced the fundamental research that has allowed US firms to lead the world in innovation. Keeping out the best and the brightest is a surefire way to ensure that other countries bridge the innovation gap.
Indian and US politicians could learn something from Singapore. A minister there told me that after launching a program to attract smart Chinese school students, he heard from angry constituents.
“These Chinese students start at the bottom of the class [because they have to learn English], but by the third year they are at the top. Our children have no chance at the top positions. Why did you start such a terrible program?” they said.
The minister replied that Singapore has no choice but to be globally competitive.
“In 15 years, when your kids get jobs, would you rather these Chinese kids competed on their side because they grew up here, or against them?” he asked.
Parents understood and the complaints died down.
The argument that manufacturing left the US because other countries used unfair practices to attract production is another version of the victimhood narrative. Apple has not had significant US-based manufacturing since 2004, so the Trump administration proposes to reshore production of iPhones, which has always been outsourced largely to Asia, by levying high tariffs on iPhone imports.
However, analysts note that the cost of an iPhone would soar if it had to be manufactured in the US. It is manufactured elsewhere not because other countries cheat, but because they are more cost efficient.
If Apple complies with the government’s wishes and brings iPhone manufacturing to the US, the high price would cause iPhone sales to plummet worldwide. Apple generates a lot of revenue from high-margin services that it sells to iPhone users through the App Store, iCloud and Apple Music, but these would drop significantly as the number of users declines. The value that might be created by bringing manufacturing back to the US would likely be more than offset by the loss of service revenues — revealing yet another hidden cost of acting on the victimhood refrain.
Rather than blaming others and leveling the economy down, it is better to level the economy up by focusing on improving the capabilities, and thus the opportunities, of those falling behind.
But try telling that to politicians.
Raghuram G. Rajan, a former governor of the Reserve Bank of India and chief economist of the IMF, is a professor of finance at the University of Chicago Booth School of Business.
Copyright: Project Syndicate
Jaw Shaw-kong (趙少康), former chairman of Broadcasting Corp of China and leader of the “blue fighters,” recently announced that he had canned his trip to east Africa, and he would stay in Taiwan for the recall vote on Saturday. He added that he hoped “his friends in the blue camp would follow his lead.” His statement is quite interesting for a few reasons. Jaw had been criticized following media reports that he would be traveling in east Africa during the recall vote. While he decided to stay in Taiwan after drawing a lot of flak, his hesitation says it all: If
When Democratic Progressive Party (DPP) caucus whip Ker Chien-ming (柯建銘) first suggested a mass recall of Chinese Nationalist Party (KMT) legislators, the Taipei Times called the idea “not only absurd, but also deeply undemocratic” (“Lai’s speech and legislative chaos,” Jan. 6, page 8). In a subsequent editorial (“Recall chaos plays into KMT hands,” Jan. 9, page 8), the paper wrote that his suggestion was not a solution, and that if it failed, it would exacerbate the enmity between the parties and lead to a cascade of revenge recalls. The danger came from having the DPP orchestrate a mass recall. As it transpired,
Elbridge Colby, America’s Under Secretary of Defense for Policy, is the most influential voice on defense strategy in the Second Trump Administration. For insight into his thinking, one could do no better than read his thoughts on the defense of Taiwan which he gathered in a book he wrote in 2021. The Strategy of Denial, is his contemplation of China’s rising hegemony in Asia and on how to deter China from invading Taiwan. Allowing China to absorb Taiwan, he wrote, would open the entire Indo-Pacific region to Chinese preeminence and result in a power transition that would place America’s prosperity
All 24 Chinese Nationalist Party (KMT) lawmakers and suspended Hsinchu Mayor Ann Kao (高虹安), formerly of the Taiwan People’s Party (TPP), survived recall elections against them on Saturday, in a massive loss to the unprecedented mass recall movement, as well as to the ruling Democratic Progressive Party (DPP) that backed it. The outcome has surprised many, as most analysts expected that at least a few legislators would be ousted. Over the past few months, dedicated and passionate civic groups gathered more than 1 million signatures to recall KMT lawmakers, an extraordinary achievement that many believed would be enough to remove at