Inflation is back, and it is demonstrating its usual tenacity. In the US, the inflation rate rose from 1.2 percent in 2020 to 4.7 percent in 2021 and 8.1 percent last year. The forecast for this year is 3.5 percent, but recent figures have shown a disappointingly modest decline. As of February, the US annual inflation rate was 6 percent, but core inflation (excluding volatile energy and food prices) had increased by 0.5 percent and remained high at 5.5 percent.
Inflation in the eurozone is demonstrating similar persistence. The annual rate increased from 0.3 percent in 2020 to 2.6 percent in 2021 and 8.4 percent last year, and while it is expected to decline to 5.6 percent this year, recent figures, like in the US, have been disappointing. In February, annual inflation decreased only slightly to 8.5 percent (from 8.6 percent in January), while core inflation increased to 5.6 percent (from 5.3 percent in January).
Far from being confined to the US and Europe, high inflation is a global phenomenon, with nations such as Turkey and Argentina reporting record-breaking rates above 70 percent. Indeed, among large economies, only China and Japan have managed to maintain price stability. It is a pattern that raises anew old questions. What causes inflation and what should policymakers do to prevent it from becoming endemic?
Illustration: Mountain People
It has become standard to look at different price components to identify what is contributing most to headline inflation. Obviously, energy prices come to mind and some observers have deemed today’s price rises “Putin’s inflation,” owing to the undeniable role that Russia’s invasion of Ukraine played in driving up firm and household energy costs last year. This interpretation has encouraged hope that inflation would be much lower this year, since energy prices are not expected to rise further this year and perhaps even to decline. Accordingly, some commentators in the US and Europe warn that monetary-policy tightening by the US Federal Reserve and the European Central Bank (ECB) risks overshooting.
Such warnings are premature, if not counterproductive. Inflation tends to become persistent because of second-round effects. Not only have producer prices risen much more during this period, but they have also not yet been fully passed through the value chain. Moreover, nominal wages have already increased or will do this year. For example, this year’s wage increases agreed between trade unions and employer organizations in the eurozone already amount to 5 percent, according to the ECB. Since firms will try to pass these costs to their customers, core inflation will probably remain higher than professional forecasts currently suggest.
More importantly, focusing on the relative strength of price components (such as energy prices) as a causal factor overstates the microeconomic foundation of macroeconomics. Inflation still is what it always has been — a macroeconomic phenomenon that results from the disequilibrium of aggregate demand and aggregate supply. As such, it is influenced by monetary and fiscal policy.
To illustrate this point, recall where we were in 2021. At 4.7 percent, the inflation rate in the US was already high and in the eurozone, it had started to accelerate by the second half of the year. Energy prices in the eurozone were rising considerably and contributing heavily to inflation before Russia invaded Ukraine. After the invasion, US markets were not particularly affected by the war’s price effects, but inflation continued to rise.
How, then, did this inflation come about?
In 2020-2021, fiscal and monetary policy became highly expansionary as policymakers rushed to dampen the economic effects of the COVID-19 pandemic and stabilize the economy. This happened globally, but it was particularly pronounced in the US, where the fiscal stimulus mobilized by the administrations of former US president Donald Trump and US President Joe Biden was larger than the pandemic-driven decline in GDP.
Moreover, US fiscal-policy expansion was accommodated by expansionary monetary policy, as the Fed stepped in to support aggregate demand. Making matters worse, aggregate supply fell at the same time, owing to disruptions in transportation, value chains and the labor market, and because the US economy is uniquely able to affect prices in international markets, its own bout of inflation spilled over to other nations, not least smaller economies within the EU.
The fiscal and monetary-policy mix was similar in Europe. The ECB purchased government bonds through its existing Public Sector Purchase Program (the PSPP, established by then-ECB president Mario Draghi in 2015) and its new Pandemic Emergency Purchase Program (PEPP). With tax revenue down (owing to the COVID-19 crisis) and government spending up to support large stimulus programs, the ECB thus refinanced member states’ sharply higher budget deficits in secondary markets. Monetary financing of fiscal policy became effective in the real economy through higher transfer spending, public consumption and public investment. Price pressures therefore increased.
After the 2008 financial crisis, Queen Elizabeth II famously asked why nobody saw it coming. One could ask the same thing about the new inflation. In the US, monetary policymakers and many commentators argued that inflation in 2021 was only temporary. In a prominent exchange with former US secretary of the treasury Lawrence Summers, Paul Krugman of the New York Times made this point again and again. In Europe, the leading figure in the debate was Philip Lane, the ECB chief economist who continued to describe inflation as a temporary phenomenon even into last year.
Tax policies in Germany (the largest eurozone economy) tended to support this view. The German government had cut the headline rate of the value-added tax from 19 percent to 16 percent for six months from July to December 2020, leading to the higher inflation figures recorded in subsequent months. In its annual report of November 2020, the German Council of Economic Experts estimated that this policy would add 1 percentage point of inflation.
In addition, Germany had announced an increase of its energy levies as of Jan. 1, 2021, extending carbon pricing to buildings and traffic. According to the council, that contributed up to another 1 percentage point to the inflation rate. Together with the base effect in energy prices overall, these temporary policies were used to make the case that the resulting inflation would be temporary, too, and, of course, similar justifications were offered by “Team Temporary” in other nations.
However, there were also many voices warning against this interpretation, most prominently Summers, who, in the spring of 2021, criticized Biden’s fiscal stimulus for being far too large. The situation reminded him of the 1960s, when policymakers overestimated the economy’s ability to cope with a highly expansionary fiscal policy out of an eagerness to accommodate conflicting demands and social concerns. Inflation rose from 2 percent to 6 percent between 1966 and 1969, well before the economy was hit by the first oil-price shock. The parallels should now be obvious. Today’s inflation had already emerged before the supply shock caused by the Western sanctions in response to Russia’s aggression.
Similarly, in a now-famous Christmas lecture in December 2020, Hans-Werner Sinn of the University of Munich warned that the eurozone’s highly expansionary fiscal and monetary policy mix would lead to a future of higher inflation. Back then, his views were dismissed with a smile by all those fiscal-stimulus aficionados on social media (who are always and everywhere advocating higher government spending). Since his lecture, Sinn has since elaborated on his argument in his book Die Wundersame Geldvermehrung (The Miraculous Multiplication of Money).
Sinn’s viewpoint is at its heart monetarist — he emphasizes that the monetary base in the eurozone has grown extremely rapidly in recent years, from 1.2 trillion euros (US$1.3 trillion) in March 2014 to 6 trillion euros in September 2021, but he also highlights the sharp growth in gross public debt among EU member states, from 73 percent of GDP in 1998 to 97 percent in 2020, with the lowest figure (66 percent) recorded in 2007. Since 2015, the ECB — or more precisely, the euro system — has purchased government bonds in secondary markets, thus refinancing expansionary fiscal policy.
More intriguingly, Sinn describes the transmission process exactly. When EU member states were hit by the COVID-19 shock, aggregate supply and aggregate demand fell. The ECB and national governments then reacted with expansionary monetary and fiscal policies, thus keeping aggregate demand high, but aggregate supply remained suppressed because of distortions in value chains, labor-market shortages and other production issues. With too much money chasing too few goods, prices duly rose.
It turns out that the Sinn of 2020 was a visionary. Why did no one listen to him?
In the preface to his book, he notes that his Christmas lecture had received 1.6 million views online between December 2020 and the summer of 2021, but even if his argument was heard, it did not stick, because modern macroeconomists had come to believe that monetarist thinking was outdated. Indeed, Sinn had been warning for years that the ECB’s monetary policy would end up producing higher inflation, but eurozone inflation remained low from 2015 to 2019.
There is an important distinction to be made here between fiscal and monetary policy. During the earlier period of unconventional monetary policy, when the ECB was purchasing assets through the PSPP, the liquidity injections remained largely in the European banking sector, where they helped to consolidate banks’ balance sheets by allowing them to write off non-performing loans against profits from monetary-policy programs. By contrast, the pandemic-era PEPP refinanced member states’ expansionary fiscal policies more directly. With this mechanism in operation, Sinn no longer needed arguments about monetary overhang and the like.
In any case, with its emphasis on the impact of excessive public debt, Sinn’s book complements other recent works warning of a revival of inflation. For example, in their 2020 book The Great Demographic Reversal, Charles Goodhart of the London School of Economics and Political Science and Manoj Pradhan of Talking Heads Macro argue that societal aging would slow economic growth, reduce household savings and increase the fiscal burden, because smaller cohorts of younger people would be supporting a larger share of retirees. These forces create inflationary pressures on their own and the reduction in globalization dynamics only add to them, by removing some of the structural elements that have kept prices subdued.
In 2013, another prophet who glimpsed the end of price moderation, Brigitte Granville of Queen Mary University of London, published Remembering Inflation, which emphasized the role that fiscal policy has played in inflation historically. Examining the origins of inflation, she starts with Peter Bernholz’s 2003 analysis of 12 case studies in which the monetary financing of budget deficits led to very high inflation, but Granville takes this analysis further by systematically highlighting the importance of intertemporal budget constraints on public finances. There is always a danger when public debt increases faster than the real rate of economic growth. To account for this fully, one must consider the credibility of monetary and fiscal policies, as well as potential conflicts and complementarities between monetary and financial stability.
Granville’s conclusion is crystal clear — “[M]onetary policy on its own can do nothing in the long term to bring order to the public finances and to increase real income; but high public debt can seriously increase inflation expectations. In other words ... money is the droit du seigneur, but the seigneur should not put his hand in the till. No sleight of hand can prevent the loss of credibility, and from this flows great distress.”
Sinn, Goodhart, Pradhan and Granville all emphasize the impact of excessive public debt on inflation, but John H. Cochrane of the Hoover Institution has now provided the most systematic and elaborate analysis of this phenomenon. His new book, The Fiscal Theory of the Price Level, is the fruit of many years of work and ultimately offers a new starting point for a critical debate on the topic.
As Cochrane explained in a fall last year article in the Journal of Economic Perspectives, the fiscal theory of the price level (FTPL) states that “inflation adjusts so that the real value of government debt equals the present value of primary surpluses.” Government debt is an asset that retains its value only as long as it promises to buy goods and services in the future, which in turn depends on the government repaying its debt at maturity.
The real question, then, is whether the government will generate enough surpluses in the future to repay its debt. Debt today is worth only as much as the government can repay in the future, just as the value of shares today can be described by the expected discounted future dividends. The FTPL describes the real price level as a function of debt, future surpluses and the respective discount rate. Consequently, it is not suggesting a fateful relationship between inflation and debt. Rather, it states that today’s real value of debt needs to be adapted if sufficient future primary surpluses become increasingly unlikely. Inflation becomes equivalent to default.
This reasoning opens new perspectives on many issues, from the role of expectations and fiscal sustainability to the importance of fiscal rules and monetary regimes. For example, it turns out that a lack of fiscal sustainability can be a decisive cause of inflation (if the debt is higher than the amount of repayment that people think the government will be willing and able to accomplish).
Finally, the FTPL also sheds new light on the role of government bonds as safe assets. Markus Brunnermeier of Princeton University and his coauthors address this issue in a recent paper, showing that the safe-asset function can add a bubble component to government debt if its market value exceeds its fundamental value. If such a bubble exists, public debt might be sustainable even in the absence of primary surpluses, but if a government’s future ability or willingness to repay debt comes into question, the bubble will burst. Again, fiscal-policy credibility is crucial. There is a systematic link between fiscal policy, debt sustainability and inflation.
There are several lessons to be learned (or relearned) from the return of inflation. First, inflation is a macroeconomic phenomenon. It is insufficient to look only at specific price components such as energy — let alone to take comfort in the expectation that energy prices would soon peak. Second, high inflation today is the result of too much money chasing too few goods and services. As such, inflation might prove to be more persistent than many market participants have acknowledged. Third, the interrelationship between monetary policy, fiscal policy and financial stability plays an important role in inflation, making debt sustainability and expectations crucial factors.
These lessons hold three overarching policy implications. First, monetary policy needs to become restrictive to cope with currently high inflation. Second, fiscal policy should not conflict with monetary-policy tightening. Third, fiscal policy must return to a more credible and sustainable footing. Returning to a path toward achieving primary surpluses would create fiscal space and allow for primary deficits to be deployed against future crises without a loss of credibility.
Such a policy shift would entail some risk. We know from recent developments that interactions between monetary and fiscal policy can affect financial stability. While banks hold large amounts of government bonds as risk-free assets, they also engage in maturity transformation when they turn short-term deposits into longer-term loans. When interest rates increase, government bonds lose market value, inducing write-offs on banks’ balance sheets. Banks thus need reserves that are sufficiently large to buffer these losses. If they are not, there can be a run on the bank.
In such a situation, a central bank might be forced to provide bailouts or postpone further interest-rate hikes. Financial dominance of monetary policy therefore would contribute to the persistence of inflation. Those warning that too much monetary-policy tightening would “break something” do have a point, but the argument is ultimately counterproductive in the fight against inflation.
Lars P. Feld, professor of economics at the University of Freiburg, is director of the Walter Eucken Institute.
Copyright: Project Syndicate, 2023.
The term “assassin’s mace” originates from Chinese folklore, describing a concealed weapon used by a weaker hero to defeat a stronger adversary with an unexpected strike. In more general military parlance, the concept refers to an asymmetric capability that targets a critical vulnerability of an adversary. China has found its modern equivalent of the assassin’s mace with its high-altitude electromagnetic pulse (HEMP) weapons, which are nuclear warheads detonated at a high altitude, emitting intense electromagnetic radiation capable of disabling and destroying electronics. An assassin’s mace weapon possesses two essential characteristics: strategic surprise and the ability to neutralize a core dependency.
Chinese President and Chinese Communist Party (CCP) Chairman Xi Jinping (習近平) said in a politburo speech late last month that his party must protect the “bottom line” to prevent systemic threats. The tone of his address was grave, revealing deep anxieties about China’s current state of affairs. Essentially, what he worries most about is systemic threats to China’s normal development as a country. The US-China trade war has turned white hot: China’s export orders have plummeted, Chinese firms and enterprises are shutting up shop, and local debt risks are mounting daily, causing China’s economy to flag externally and hemorrhage internally. China’s
During the “426 rally” organized by the Chinese Nationalist Party (KMT) and the Taiwan People’s Party under the slogan “fight green communism, resist dictatorship,” leaders from the two opposition parties framed it as a battle against an allegedly authoritarian administration led by President William Lai (賴清德). While criticism of the government can be a healthy expression of a vibrant, pluralistic society, and protests are quite common in Taiwan, the discourse of the 426 rally nonetheless betrayed troubling signs of collective amnesia. Specifically, the KMT, which imposed 38 years of martial law in Taiwan from 1949 to 1987, has never fully faced its
When a recall campaign targeting the opposition Chinese Nationalist Party (KMT) legislators was launched, something rather disturbing happened. According to reports, Hualien County Government officials visited several people to verify their signatures. Local authorities allegedly used routine or harmless reasons as an excuse to enter people’s house for investigation. The KMT launched its own recall campaigns, targeting Democratic Progressive Party (DPP) lawmakers, and began to collect signatures. It has been found that some of the KMT-headed counties and cities have allegedly been mobilizing municipal machinery. In Keelung, the director of the Department of Civil Affairs used the household registration system