The new electoral system for Taiwan's legislature is under heavy fire, even though it sailed through the onerous process of constitutional amendment last June with overwhelming popular support.
Progressive optimism seems to have waned. Previously people expected the electoral reform to "clean up the house." Nowadays many fear the coming of a new dark age for Taiwan's democracy.
What would Taiwan's democracy look like under the new electoral rules? Will we see ourselves redeemed? Or doomed?
That the new electoral system may drastically destabilize the status quo in domestic politics is beyond doubt. Its actual consequences, however, are far from predetermined. Much is contingent on how the new system is implemented, and how politicians and voters behave under the new rules of the game.
There are signs of trouble on the horizon, but there are also signs of hope. What we are engaging in is a democratic experiment that requires our vigilance, open-mindedness and, perhaps most importantly, some patience.
Beginning with its next term, the legislature will be composed of 113 members -- only half its current size. Of the members, 73 will be elected from the single-member districts (SMD), 34 will be elected on a party-proportional basis under a system called the "List-PR," and 6 will be representatives from the Aboriginal community.
With the sharp downsizing of the legislature, the full-scale adoption of SMD, and the creation of a separate ballot for party seats, last year's constitutional amendment radically alters the electoral system currently in use.
The reform package can be assessed in light of "governability" and "representativeness," the two main concerns of electoral engineering.
By decreasing the number of legislative seats and raising the electoral threshold in district elections, the new system seeks to create incentives for moderate and responsible politics.
The hope is to select people who are more distinguished and respectable than our incumbent legislators. A pessimistic view, however, suggests that legislative politics will become more parochial if the district elections are driven mainly by local politics.
The List-PR seats may partially counterbalance the majoritarian tendency of the winner-take-all district elections. The List-PR part of the system could facilitate a certain degree of ideological representation. The downside is that legislative politics will become no less polarized, especially if the List-PR seats are occupied mainly by partisan hardliners.
Taken as a whole, the new electoral system might be less proportional -- in terms of the vote-seat relationship -- than its predecessor. The reduction of electoral proportionality is detrimental to the survival or development of minor parties, but the new system arguably still leaves room for more than two party blocs.
Some sort of partisan realignment has already taken place as a reaction to the reform. But the systematic transition also appears to open a window of opportunity for the entry of new parties. It is difficult to predict the short-term impact of the electoral reform on Taiwan's party system.
Also ambiguous is the compatibility of the new semi-PR system and Taiwan's semi-presidential system. The conventional wisdom that proportional representation tends to produce crises of governability in presidential democracies is questionable and cannot be squarely applied to the case of Taiwan. But it is also doubtful to what extent the new system will help reduce the current stalemate or partisan warfare.
Many commentators still have other reservations about the propriety of the reform measures. Apart from concerns of representativeness, competitiveness, campaign costs, malapportionment and partisan fairness under the new system, it is of particular concern that the future legislature may have too few members to adequately perform its routine functions.
Halving the number of legislative seats is indeed the most problematic component of the reform package. Considering the error costs and transaction costs of representation and legislation as suggested by law professor Robert Cooter, few would agree that 113-seat is the legislature's optimal size.
The problem is, we don't have an optimal number of legislators, and the size calculation cannot be divorced from the design of the electoral system. Without systematic consideration and coordination, electoral engineering could easily run into inconsistency.
So, the new system is arguably neither a flawless panacea nor a deadly poison. The thrust of the structural reform is not to realize a democratic utopia, which by its very nature is impossible to achieve, but to open up the possibility for political renovation.
Predictably, the incumbents don't like the changes. Under the new system, they either stand no chance of reelection or have to fight on an unfamiliar battlefield. They and other dissenters denounce the new system as a product of reason being surrendered to misguided populism.
It may be the case that the institutional engineering of the new system was unduly influenced by populist rhetoric. But without pressure from the public, the reform package may have remained just an idea.
Electoral design is ultimately a matter of political judgment, of which volition is as critical as reason. It is an area where compromise is inevitable, and where effect is far more important than intent.
Just as the new system's populist imprint should not dictate our assessment of its reasonableness, we should not reject the reforms simply because they are tainted by the incumbents' self-serving motivations. A comprehensive constitutional reengineering, after all, is what we really need.
However, restructuring the electoral system should never be our only option. A pragmatic citizen could not agree more with Richard Rorty's admonition: "The best can be an enemy of the better." The electoral reform has neither succeeded nor failed yet. Its future success, as always, resides in our hands.
Su Yen-tu is a doctoral student at Harvard Law School.
In their recent op-ed “Trump Should Rein In Taiwan” in Foreign Policy magazine, Christopher Chivvis and Stephen Wertheim argued that the US should pressure President William Lai (賴清德) to “tone it down” to de-escalate tensions in the Taiwan Strait — as if Taiwan’s words are more of a threat to peace than Beijing’s actions. It is an old argument dressed up in new concern: that Washington must rein in Taipei to avoid war. However, this narrative gets it backward. Taiwan is not the problem; China is. Calls for a so-called “grand bargain” with Beijing — where the US pressures Taiwan into concessions
The term “assassin’s mace” originates from Chinese folklore, describing a concealed weapon used by a weaker hero to defeat a stronger adversary with an unexpected strike. In more general military parlance, the concept refers to an asymmetric capability that targets a critical vulnerability of an adversary. China has found its modern equivalent of the assassin’s mace with its high-altitude electromagnetic pulse (HEMP) weapons, which are nuclear warheads detonated at a high altitude, emitting intense electromagnetic radiation capable of disabling and destroying electronics. An assassin’s mace weapon possesses two essential characteristics: strategic surprise and the ability to neutralize a core dependency.
Chinese President and Chinese Communist Party (CCP) Chairman Xi Jinping (習近平) said in a politburo speech late last month that his party must protect the “bottom line” to prevent systemic threats. The tone of his address was grave, revealing deep anxieties about China’s current state of affairs. Essentially, what he worries most about is systemic threats to China’s normal development as a country. The US-China trade war has turned white hot: China’s export orders have plummeted, Chinese firms and enterprises are shutting up shop, and local debt risks are mounting daily, causing China’s economy to flag externally and hemorrhage internally. China’s
During the “426 rally” organized by the Chinese Nationalist Party (KMT) and the Taiwan People’s Party under the slogan “fight green communism, resist dictatorship,” leaders from the two opposition parties framed it as a battle against an allegedly authoritarian administration led by President William Lai (賴清德). While criticism of the government can be a healthy expression of a vibrant, pluralistic society, and protests are quite common in Taiwan, the discourse of the 426 rally nonetheless betrayed troubling signs of collective amnesia. Specifically, the KMT, which imposed 38 years of martial law in Taiwan from 1949 to 1987, has never fully faced its