Three years ago, the European single currency, the euro, was born at an exchange rate of 1:US$1.17, which presumably was deemed to reflect appropriately price levels on both sides of the Atlantic at that time. The euro's exchange rate has since endured a roller-coaster ride. Now, it has returned to almost exactly its opening level. So why is the European business community claiming that the "super euro" is bringing calamity down upon their heads?
The answer is that blaming the euro is an easy way to deflect attention from the true cause of Europe's economic malaise -- a surprisingly low level of productivity per capita. Europe's low productivity reflects a simple statistical fact that fatally undermines relatively high productivity per hours worked -- weak participation in the active labor force means that Europeans work a very low number of hours.
It is important to clarify a few fundamental points regarding the euro/dollar exchange rate, because this is an issue on which confusion -- often generated strategically -- pervades public debate.
First, nobody knows how to explain or predict the short-term movements (from one day to six months, say) of exchange rates. A famous academic paper about 20 years ago showed that a random walk was better at predicting short-run exchange rate movements than any fancy mathematical model based on selected economic variables.
That conclusion still applies. Nobody had a clear idea why the euro plummeted to almost US$0.80 in its first year-and-a-half of trading, and nobody could predict when it would recover. Some observers attribute the current "high" level of the euro (and thus low growth in Europe) to tight monetary policy on the part of the European Central Bank (ECB).
But if high interest rates are causing the euro's rise, why was the dollar appreciating in periods when the US Federal Reserve cut rates aggressively? People should be wary of commentators who purport to explain "why" a currency's exchange rate is doing what it is doing.
Second, exporters who blame the current level of the euro for their difficulties should wake up to reality. The current level of the euro makes prices on both sides of the Atlantic relatively similar. If an exporting firm is only profitable when the euro falls to US$0.80 or US$0.90, it better start increasing productivity fast if it is to survive with the euro back up at US$1.17.
For many years Germany and Japan dominated world exports, and at the time both the yen and the deutsche mark were among the "strongest" currencies in the world. It was innovation, and high productivity, not a weak currency, that enabled German and Japanese goods to conquer the world.
Third, the euro area is about as open to international trade as the US. The US economy was flying in the 1990s, when the dollar was strong. As was true for Germany and the deutsche mark and remains true for Japan and the yen, a strong dollar has not historically caused weak US growth.
Europeans are used to thinking of the exchange rate as a critical variable, because they live in very open economies that export close to 50 percent of their total output. But most of these exports go to other euro-zone countries, and are thus unaffected by the level of the euro. Exports outside the euro area claim only 15 percent to 16 percent of Europe's total output, and will be even less when (and if) Sweden and the UK join the euro.
So commentators, policymakers and businessmen should stop calling for the ECB to do something about the "strong euro." Central bank intervention in the currency market is merely destabilizing, and therefore counter-productive. The ECB was right to ignore the exchange rate when it fell to US$0.80, and it is right to ignore it today when it is close to US$1.20.
Most economists believe that central banks should only target inflation, which means cutting interest rates only when the economy slows down and inflation falls -- which is precisely what the ECB has been doing.
The bottom line is that Europeans should worry and talk less about the euro exchange rate, and spend the time they save trying to address their real problems -- low productivity, market rigidities, fiscal polices constrained by the Stability Pact and bankrupt pension systems. Europe's economic policymakers have enough problems on their plate. They should let the currency markets take care of the euro/dollar exchange rate.
Alberto Alesina is a professor of economics at Harvard University and Francesco Giavazzi is a professor of economics at Bocconi University in Milan.
Copyright: Project Syndicate
The term “assassin’s mace” originates from Chinese folklore, describing a concealed weapon used by a weaker hero to defeat a stronger adversary with an unexpected strike. In more general military parlance, the concept refers to an asymmetric capability that targets a critical vulnerability of an adversary. China has found its modern equivalent of the assassin’s mace with its high-altitude electromagnetic pulse (HEMP) weapons, which are nuclear warheads detonated at a high altitude, emitting intense electromagnetic radiation capable of disabling and destroying electronics. An assassin’s mace weapon possesses two essential characteristics: strategic surprise and the ability to neutralize a core dependency.
Chinese President and Chinese Communist Party (CCP) Chairman Xi Jinping (習近平) said in a politburo speech late last month that his party must protect the “bottom line” to prevent systemic threats. The tone of his address was grave, revealing deep anxieties about China’s current state of affairs. Essentially, what he worries most about is systemic threats to China’s normal development as a country. The US-China trade war has turned white hot: China’s export orders have plummeted, Chinese firms and enterprises are shutting up shop, and local debt risks are mounting daily, causing China’s economy to flag externally and hemorrhage internally. China’s
During the “426 rally” organized by the Chinese Nationalist Party (KMT) and the Taiwan People’s Party under the slogan “fight green communism, resist dictatorship,” leaders from the two opposition parties framed it as a battle against an allegedly authoritarian administration led by President William Lai (賴清德). While criticism of the government can be a healthy expression of a vibrant, pluralistic society, and protests are quite common in Taiwan, the discourse of the 426 rally nonetheless betrayed troubling signs of collective amnesia. Specifically, the KMT, which imposed 38 years of martial law in Taiwan from 1949 to 1987, has never fully faced its
When a recall campaign targeting the opposition Chinese Nationalist Party (KMT) legislators was launched, something rather disturbing happened. According to reports, Hualien County Government officials visited several people to verify their signatures. Local authorities allegedly used routine or harmless reasons as an excuse to enter people’s house for investigation. The KMT launched its own recall campaigns, targeting Democratic Progressive Party (DPP) lawmakers, and began to collect signatures. It has been found that some of the KMT-headed counties and cities have allegedly been mobilizing municipal machinery. In Keelung, the director of the Department of Civil Affairs used the household registration system