Since taking office, Premier Wu Den-yih (吳敦義) has claimed to stand for grassroots economics. We want to ask Wu this: If an economic cooperation framework agreement (ECFA) with China were to cause more harm to the grassroots economy, would he still advocate signing one?
At a press conference naming the new Cabinet last month, Wu said the signing of any cross-strait agreement should observe the principles of national need, public support and legislative oversight.
Now that the government has refused to hold a referendum on an ECFA, how can it claim to have obtained public support or to have reached a broad public consensus on the matter?
Rushing to sign an economic pact with China, the administration of President Ma Ying-jeou (馬英九) has aggressively promoted the necessity of an ECFA with Beijing and cited an assessment report by the semi-official Chung-Hua Institution for Economic Research that endorses the view that an ECFA would be favorable to the Taiwanese macro economy.
The Ministry of Economic Affairs made “expert adjustments” in line with the report to minimize or eliminate any negative impact on certain industries before coming to the conclusion that signing an ECFA with China would have substantial and positive economic results.
In fact, several of the hypotheses in the Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP) model on which the report is based defy reality.
First, the assumption of full employment excludes the possibility of unemployment.
Second, it is assumed that after signing an ECFA, tariffs on most Taiwanese industrial exports to China would be removed.
As a result, Taiwanese petrochemical products would replace petrochemical products from South Korea and Japan, which accounted for 38 percent — US$38 billion — of the Chinese market in 2007, while Taiwanese mechanical products would replace corresponding products from South Korea and ASEAN countries, which accounted for 23 percent — US$27 billion — of the Chinese market.
These assumptions are entirely unrealistic. Tariffs are not the only factor affecting product competitiveness, and petrochemical and mechanical products are not identical from country to country. Thus, it is out of the question that Taiwanese products would replace other products.
In addition, production capacity of the Taiwanese petrochemical and mechanical industries is not sufficient to replace products manufactured by Japan, South Korea and the ASEAN countries.
Worse, the GTAP model uses market overlap to estimate replacement levels, but it only considers the possibility that Chinese products may replace products from Japan, South Korea and ASEAN countries in the Taiwanese market, failing to mention the possibility that they may also replace Taiwanese products. This is the most significant problem, and the one that will most affect Taiwan’s market.
Since labor costs and rent in China are far lower than in Taiwan, cheap and inferior Chinese products and agricultural produce will likely enter the nation on a large scale under zero-tariff preferential treatment. The influx of Chinese products will cause domestic agriculture and industry to collapse — especially small and medium-sized enterprises manufacturing towels, ready-made garments, shoes, bedding and ceramics — and raise unemployment levels even higher.
The result of increasing unemployment in Taiwan will be depressed wages and increased income inequality.
Wang To-far is a part-time professor of economics at National Taipei University.
TRANSLATED BY TED YANG
Elbridge Colby, America’s Under Secretary of Defense for Policy, is the most influential voice on defense strategy in the Second Trump Administration. For insight into his thinking, one could do no better than read his thoughts on the defense of Taiwan which he gathered in a book he wrote in 2021. The Strategy of Denial, is his contemplation of China’s rising hegemony in Asia and on how to deter China from invading Taiwan. Allowing China to absorb Taiwan, he wrote, would open the entire Indo-Pacific region to Chinese preeminence and result in a power transition that would place America’s prosperity
A few weeks ago in Kaohsiung, tech mogul turned political pundit Robert Tsao (曹興誠) joined Western Washington University professor Chen Shih-fen (陳時奮) for a public forum in support of Taiwan’s recall campaign. Kaohsiung, already the most Taiwanese independence-minded city in Taiwan, was not in need of a recall. So Chen took a different approach: He made the case that unification with China would be too expensive to work. The argument was unusual. Most of the time, we hear that Taiwan should remain free out of respect for democracy and self-determination, but cost? That is not part of the usual script, and
All 24 Chinese Nationalist Party (KMT) lawmakers and suspended Hsinchu Mayor Ann Kao (高虹安), formerly of the Taiwan People’s Party (TPP), survived recall elections against them on Saturday, in a massive loss to the unprecedented mass recall movement, as well as to the ruling Democratic Progressive Party (DPP) that backed it. The outcome has surprised many, as most analysts expected that at least a few legislators would be ousted. Over the past few months, dedicated and passionate civic groups gathered more than 1 million signatures to recall KMT lawmakers, an extraordinary achievement that many believed would be enough to remove at
Behind the gloating, the Chinese Nationalist Party (KMT) must be letting out a big sigh of relief. Its powerful party machine saved the day, but it took that much effort just to survive a challenge mounted by a humble group of active citizens, and in areas where the KMT is historically strong. On the other hand, the Democratic Progressive Party (DPP) must now realize how toxic a brand it has become to many voters. The campaigners’ amateurism is what made them feel valid and authentic, but when the DPP belatedly inserted itself into the campaign, it did more harm than good. The