Samuel Johnson called patriotism "the last refuge of a scoundrel." If that is true, what should we think of today's mounting economic nationalism, sometimes euphemistically described as "economic patriotism?"
Indeed, economic nationalism is exceptionally vigorous at the moment. Vigorous popular opposition to a Dubai company's plan to take over ports in the US shocked the American government. Poland is witnessing a populist backlash against foreign ownership of banks. France is blocking the acquisition of French utilities by the Italian electricity company Enel. Together with other European governments, France is also agitating against the takeover of the Luxembourg-based steel company Arcelor by a Netherlands company largely controlled by an Indian steel magnate.
Defenders of these ill-fated cross-border takeovers worry that a sinister whiff of the 20th century's worst moments is in the air. An outraged Italian minister warned of a new mobilization of populist nationalism in an "August 1914" scenario. The better analogy is from the 1930s: In 1933, the year in which Hitler came to power, the world's most famous economist, John Maynard Keynes, produced a plea for "national self-sufficiency."
Both the 1914 and the 1933 analogies point to the most striking characteristic of the current debate: the key role of security worries in justifying protectionism. Nobody worried about foreign ownership of US ports as long as the owner was a British company; the new fears reflect the belief that Dubai might be a channel for Islamic fundamentalism and terrorism.
Likewise, the deterioration of international relations before World War I and World War II was marked by governments' increased propensity to use economics as a tool of power politics. In 1911, the diplomatic crisis over Morocco was accompanied by a French speculative attack on German financial markets. In the 1930s, both France and Germany used this kind of technique as a way to bolster their own security. The US tried to control Japanese expansion in Asia by limiting Japan's energy (especially petroleum) imports.
The most obvious reason for increased worries about security in the US is the challenge of meeting the threat of terrorism after the attacks of September 2001. But that can scarcely explain European nervousness and the protectionist reaction.
In Europe's case, two contrasting explanations exist. The first is that the new worries are a strange case of psychological transference. People in places like France and Poland who worry about national decline seek to blame somebody outside the country.
There was certainly a great deal of this type of sentiment in the 1930s, when the populist response to the Great Depression attributed it to the sinister forces of "international capital." The modern version of this explanation holds that the world is changing so quickly that national security and, indeed, national identity, are under threat.
An alternative scenario suggests that these fears emanate from a real problem. Modern economic growth still depends in almost every advanced industrial country on imported energy (Norway is an exception). Because of fears about pollution, or about the safety of nuclear energy, most countries neglected to build up their own capacity.
The resulting vulnerability was highlighted by the Russian reduction of gas supplies to Ukraine in January, which resulted in reduced flows to central and western Europe. The experience made Poles particularly jittery, and pushed the country's populist right-wing government down the road of economic nationalism. But West Europeans remember their own traumas, including electricity grid failures and widespread blackouts. Wouldn't an Italian company facing grid failure prefer to shut down French rather than Italian consumers?
These two scenarios of the origins of economic nationalism, one irrational and the other not, are not real alternatives, but describe responses that intertwine: the more rational the fear, the more that fear can be used as an instrument of politics.
Fear creates a demand for state action. Politicians like this because it increases demand for their services. They point out the potential problem and then attempt to sell solutions that lie within their nationally defined spheres of competence.
One modern politician, in particular, has been effective in placing nervousness about energy supply at the center of a new political vision. According to Russian President Vladimir Putin, the need to control and secure energy justifies a massive extension of state intervention in the economy.
Putin's vision was apparently vindicated by the aftermath of the terrorist attacks on the US. Since then, Putin has projected his vision of politicized energy in a way that makes all Europeans, not just Russians, nervous. That bolsters his strength in the Russian setting. But a Putin in one country has a tendency to produce Putin imitators elsewhere.
We should be concerned about the efficiency losses in markets where restrictions stemming from economic nationalism have so far been imposed. But we should be far more worried that fear about the collapse or manipulation of markets creates a demand for action that makes such a collapse more rather than less likely. Fear generates a demand for more security that is in the end paralyzing.
Harold James is professor of history and international affairs at Princeton University.
Copyright: Project Syndicate
US President Donald Trump and Chinese President Xi Jinping (習近平) were born under the sign of Gemini. Geminis are known for their intelligence, creativity, adaptability and flexibility. It is unlikely, then, that the trade conflict between the US and China would escalate into a catastrophic collision. It is more probable that both sides would seek a way to de-escalate, paving the way for a Trump-Xi summit that allows the global economy some breathing room. Practically speaking, China and the US have vulnerabilities, and a prolonged trade war would be damaging for both. In the US, the electoral system means that public opinion
In their recent op-ed “Trump Should Rein In Taiwan” in Foreign Policy magazine, Christopher Chivvis and Stephen Wertheim argued that the US should pressure President William Lai (賴清德) to “tone it down” to de-escalate tensions in the Taiwan Strait — as if Taiwan’s words are more of a threat to peace than Beijing’s actions. It is an old argument dressed up in new concern: that Washington must rein in Taipei to avoid war. However, this narrative gets it backward. Taiwan is not the problem; China is. Calls for a so-called “grand bargain” with Beijing — where the US pressures Taiwan into concessions
They did it again. For the whole world to see: an image of a Taiwan flag crushed by an industrial press, and the horrifying warning that “it’s closer than you think.” All with the seal of authenticity that only a reputable international media outlet can give. The Economist turned what looks like a pastiche of a poster for a grim horror movie into a truth everyone can digest, accept, and use to support exactly the opinion China wants you to have: It is over and done, Taiwan is doomed. Four years after inaccurately naming Taiwan the most dangerous place on
The term “assassin’s mace” originates from Chinese folklore, describing a concealed weapon used by a weaker hero to defeat a stronger adversary with an unexpected strike. In more general military parlance, the concept refers to an asymmetric capability that targets a critical vulnerability of an adversary. China has found its modern equivalent of the assassin’s mace with its high-altitude electromagnetic pulse (HEMP) weapons, which are nuclear warheads detonated at a high altitude, emitting intense electromagnetic radiation capable of disabling and destroying electronics. An assassin’s mace weapon possesses two essential characteristics: strategic surprise and the ability to neutralize a core dependency.