US Federal Reserve Governor Ben Bernanke has blamed net inflows of capital from the rest of the world, especially China, for a global saving glut that is driving up the US current account deficit.
Unfortunately, some commentators have echoed this seemingly plausible but outrageously silly idea.
For example, an HSBC economist in Hong Kong, Qu Hongbin (
In all events, the observations cited above reflect a belief that China must lower its domestic saving rate to fuel its economic growth and correct its trade imbalance. Doubtless, part of this argument's credibility lays in China's domestic saving rate of 46 percent of earnings.
But Bernanke and his followers confuse cause and effect in suggesting that an "excess" amount of global savings is the cause of the US' current account deficit, despite low interest rates.
As it is, their macroeconomic analysis is blind to basic economic realities. In the first instance, they are unable to unravel why savers continue to pour money into banks despite ultra-low deposit rates on offer. It turns out that the inflow of funds into banks is the result of monetary pumping by most central banks, which has generated a massive bubble inflated by excessive formation of credit and liquidity.
Bernanke's assertion is also flawed for implying that "excess" savings can damage an economy since "too much" capital can be accumulated. But capital formation is an essential element of economic growth that drives higher living standards.
As such, the implication of his argument is that there is too much growth and people are too well off for their own good. It is a little shocking that such a notion passes intellectual muster.
In all events, the conceptualization offered by Bernanke conveniently ignores the role played by the US Federal Reserve Board in causing the US trade deficit to rise while the dollar has weakened (the current account deficit of the US last year was US$668 billion, or 5.7 percent of GDP, with further rises expected).
In fact, these arguments are redolent of the warmed-over notion of John Maynard Keynes known as the "paradox of thrift." Like Keynes, Bernanke confuses the demand for money (hoarding) with savings and suggest that large cash balances reduce overall demand. But increased savings remain available in the financial system to be lent to investors.
As such, the inflows of foreign funds into the US are not savings, nor can they be fully explained by a strong domestic US capital market. Nor can it be said that the strength of the US economy is pushing up the current account deficit into record territory. If this were the case, the value of the dollar would not have recorded the general weakening trend that was reversed only recently (the US dollar is up by about 7 percent against a basket of major currencies so far this year).
The growing US current account deficit has been driven by ultra-loose monetary policy. America's central bankers have overseen an increase in the money supply (measured as M1) by 27 percent from January 2001 to last December.
As such, the accumulated dollar reserves held by central banks in countries with trade surpluses with the US reflects a type of hoarding that does not reflect increased savings. But these trade surpluses are temporary, since they eventually will be used to purchase imported goods or dollar-based assets like Maytag and Unocal.
The cheap credit policy of the Fed has created an excess supply of dollars domestically and internationally. Low interest rates in the US led to higher spending and nominal incomes, which drove up the demand for imports, causing the trade deficit to balloon. With the dollar pouring relentlessly into foreign exchange markets, the trend has been for it to depreciate against other currencies and many commodities, like oil and gold.
And so it is that this flood of cheap credit, courtesy of US central bankers, has created and kept afloat a gigantic, global Ponzi scheme. Like all pyramid schemes, there is a false sense of shared prosperity. Americans get cheap imports that hold down domestic consumer prices. And foreigners are happy, thinking that they are enjoying export-driven growth while accumulating more dollars, or paper debt mostly denominated in dollars.
Eventually, foreigners will find that their addiction to bits of green money in exchange for their own hard work is doing damage to their economies. Presumably, China will recognize this before it is too late.
But this would require that it abandon the neo-Mercantilist logic that supports the obsession with a "weak" currency to promote exports.
Artificially low interest rates have spawned a global credit bubble that has caused various "imbalances." These include a global housing boom and a trade deficit in the US that is responsible for the massive foreign exchange holdings in economies with trade surpluses. In the case of China, it has also generated an unsustainable and temporary burst of growth in its export-oriented industries. The excess liquidity is also responsible for higher asset prices, especially gold and oil.
History reveals that all "bubbles" either deflate or burst. In either case, an economic slowdown occurs that requires the liquidation of misguided investments that involve unsupported productive capacity.
It is both interesting and troubling to recount the history of Asia's export-led powerhouses. The bursting of Japan's bubble in 1989 ended a long period of high economic growth that was followed by a long period of low growth that continues to this day.
And then East Asia's "miracle" economies hit a wall in 1997 and 1998 that burst their bubbles. It should be rather clear that China is next, so the most pressing question becomes, when?
Christopher Lingle is visiting professor of economics at Universidad Francisco Marroquin in Guatemala.
On May 7, 1971, Henry Kissinger planned his first, ultra-secret mission to China and pondered whether it would be better to meet his Chinese interlocutors “in Pakistan where the Pakistanis would tape the meeting — or in China where the Chinese would do the taping.” After a flicker of thought, he decided to have the Chinese do all the tape recording, translating and transcribing. Fortuitously, historians have several thousand pages of verbatim texts of Dr. Kissinger’s negotiations with his Chinese counterparts. Paradoxically, behind the scenes, Chinese stenographers prepared verbatim English language typescripts faster than they could translate and type them
More than 30 years ago when I immigrated to the US, applied for citizenship and took the 100-question civics test, the one part of the naturalization process that left the deepest impression on me was one question on the N-400 form, which asked: “Have you ever been a member of, involved in or in any way associated with any communist or totalitarian party anywhere in the world?” Answering “yes” could lead to the rejection of your application. Some people might try their luck and lie, but if exposed, the consequences could be much worse — a person could be fined,
Xiaomi Corp founder Lei Jun (雷軍) on May 22 made a high-profile announcement, giving online viewers a sneak peek at the company’s first 3-nanometer mobile processor — the Xring O1 chip — and saying it is a breakthrough in China’s chip design history. Although Xiaomi might be capable of designing chips, it lacks the ability to manufacture them. No matter how beautifully planned the blueprints are, if they cannot be mass-produced, they are nothing more than drawings on paper. The truth is that China’s chipmaking efforts are still heavily reliant on the free world — particularly on Taiwan Semiconductor Manufacturing
Last week, Nvidia chief executive officer Jensen Huang (黃仁勳) unveiled the location of Nvidia’s new Taipei headquarters and announced plans to build the world’s first large-scale artificial intelligence (AI) supercomputer in Taiwan. In Taipei, Huang’s announcement was welcomed as a milestone for Taiwan’s tech industry. However, beneath the excitement lies a significant question: Can Taiwan’s electricity infrastructure, especially its renewable energy supply, keep up with growing demand from AI chipmaking? Despite its leadership in digital hardware, Taiwan lags behind in renewable energy adoption. Moreover, the electricity grid is already experiencing supply shortages. As Taiwan’s role in AI manufacturing expands, it is critical that