Modern economists have turned Adam Smith into a prophet, just as Communist regimes once deified Karl Marx. The central tenet they attribute to Smith -- that good incentives, regardless of culture, produce good results -- has become the great commandment of economics. Yet that view is a mistaken interpretation of history (and probably a mistaken reading of Smith).
Modern growth came not from better incentives, but from the creation of a new economic culture in societies like England and Scotland. To get poor societies to grow, we need to change their cultures, not just their institutions and associated incentives, and that requires exposing more people in these societies to life in advanced economies. Despite the almost universal belief by economists in the primacy of incentives, three features of world history demonstrate the dominance of culture.
In the past, excellent governments -- that is, governments that fully incentivized the citizenry -- have gone hand in hand with economic stagnation.
The incentives for economic activity are much better in most poor economies, including pre-industrial economies, than in such prosperous and contented economies as Germany or Sweden.
The Industrial Revolution itself was the product of changes in basic economic preferences of people ind England, not changes in institutions.
TEXTILE EXAMPLE
For example, the cotton textile industry that developed in Bombay between 1857 and 1947 operated with no employment restrictions, complete security of capital, a stable and efficient legal system, no import or export controls, freedom of entry by entrepreneurs from around the world and free access to the British market. Moreover, it had access to some of the world's cheapest capital and labor, in an industry where labor accounted for more than 60 percent of manufacturing costs. Profit rates of only 6percent to 8 percent in the early 20th century were enough to induce construction of new mills. Yet India's textile industry could not compete against Britain's, even though British wages were five times higher. Incentives alone could not produce growth.
At the opposite end of the spectrum, Scandinavia is notorious among economists for its high taxes and government spending. Wage income is effectively taxed at a whopping rate of 50 percent to 67 percent. Economic activity is everywhere hedged by rules, regulations and restrictions. Yet these are successful economies, producing as much per worker hour as the US and growing steadily.
MEDIEVAL ENGLAND
By contrast, in medieval England, typical tax rates on labor and capital income were 1 percent or less, and labor and product markets were free and competitive. Yet there was no economic growth. Even though assets such as land were completely secure (in most English villages, land had passed from owner to owner unchallenged through the courts for 800 years or more), investors had to be paid real returns of 10 percent to hold land.
The Industrial Revolution occurred in a setting where the economy's basic institutional incentives were unchanged for hundreds of years, and, if anything, were getting worse. Yet, over the centuries, the responses to these incentives gradually strengthened and entrepreneurship took hold. Profit opportunities from converting common land into private land, which had existed since the Middle Ages, were finally pursued. Roads that had been largely impassable from neglect for hundreds of years were repaired and improved by local efforts.
The rate of return required on safe investments declined from 10 percent to 4 percent. Thus the crucial determinants of wealth and poverty are not differences in incentives, but differences in how people respond to them. In successful economies, people work hard, accumulate, and innovate even when their incentives are poor. In failed economies, people work little, save little, and stick with outmoded techniques even when incentives are good.
How can we transform the economic cultures of poor societies to be more like rich ones?
When workers move from a poor to a rich economy, there is rapid adaptation to the economic mores of the new society. In the textile industry in the early 20th century, for example, output per worker hour of Polish workers in New England was four times greater than that of Polish workers using the same machines in Poland. One reason for illegal migration from the poor to the rich economies is the ability of many such migrants to adapt to economic life in rich economies.
Migrants accustomed to conditions in successful economies are a potential nucleus for industrialization in poor societies. But these workers usually choose to remain in rich economies. A skilled Nigerian immigrant in the US, for example, has more opportunities there than if he returned to Nigeria. The flow of migrants is all from poor to rich economies, particularly for workers with skills and education.
Thus, the problem is to engineer a sufficient flow of return migration to poor societies by those with exposure to the social conditions of economically successful societies.
Aid to poor societies in the form of programs designed to expose their students and workers to the experience of living and working in the US before returning home will be more effective than trying to make these societies' governments and institutions more like those of the advanced economies. People come first.
Gregory Clark is chairman of the economics department at University of California at Davis. Copyright: Project Syndicate
Speaking at the Copenhagen Democracy Summit on May 13, former president Tsai Ing-wen (蔡英文) said that democracies must remain united and that “Taiwan’s security is essential to regional stability and to defending democratic values amid mounting authoritarianism.” Earlier that day, Tsai had met with a group of Danish parliamentarians led by Danish Parliament Speaker Pia Kjaersgaard, who has visited Taiwan many times, most recently in November last year, when she met with President William Lai (賴清德) at the Presidential Office. Kjaersgaard had told Lai: “I can assure you that ... you can count on us. You can count on our support
Denmark has consistently defended Greenland in light of US President Donald Trump’s interests and has provided unwavering support to Ukraine during its war with Russia. Denmark can be proud of its clear support for peoples’ democratic right to determine their own future. However, this democratic ideal completely falls apart when it comes to Taiwan — and it raises important questions about Denmark’s commitment to supporting democracies. Taiwan lives under daily military threats from China, which seeks to take over Taiwan, by force if necessary — an annexation that only a very small minority in Taiwan supports. Denmark has given China a
Many local news media over the past week have reported on Internet personality Holger Chen’s (陳之漢) first visit to China between Tuesday last week and yesterday, as remarks he made during a live stream have sparked wide discussions and strong criticism across the Taiwan Strait. Chen, better known as Kuan Chang (館長), is a former gang member turned fitness celebrity and businessman. He is known for his live streams, which are full of foul-mouthed and hypermasculine commentary. He had previously spoken out against the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) and criticized Taiwanese who “enjoy the freedom in Taiwan, but want China’s money”
A high-school student surnamed Yang (楊) gained admissions to several prestigious medical schools recently. However, when Yang shared his “learning portfolio” on social media, he was caught exaggerating and even falsifying content, and his admissions were revoked. Now he has to take the “advanced subjects test” scheduled for next month. With his outstanding performance in the general scholastic ability test (GSAT), Yang successfully gained admissions to five prestigious medical schools. However, his university dreams have now been frustrated by the “flaws” in his learning portfolio. This is a wake-up call not only for students, but also teachers. Yang did make a big