If there is one thing that the White House wants us to know about the new tariffs that promise to upend the global economy, it is that they are “reciprocal.”
We now know that they are not reciprocal at all. In fact, they bear no connection whatsoever to any levies that the target country might impose on US exports. They are simply designed to be proportional to that country’s trade deficit with the US, adjusted for the size of their bilateral trade.
That is not a formula that anyone expected — for good reason, since no economic or moral logic justifies it. However, in retrospect it appears a natural consequence of how US President Donald Trump erroneously conceives of global trade. Tragically, Trump’s misconceptions also mean that his policy choices would be way worse for US consumers, investors and partners.
Illustration: Yusha
Suppose you, like Trump, want to reduce the US’ overall trade deficit with the world to zero. Forcing your bilateral trade deficit with each country down to zero — the ultimate aim of that tariff formula — is an absurdly inefficient way to go about it.
In fact, tariffs proportional to a country’s trade deficit with the US actually seem designed to maximize the pain to US consumers. The very countries that have retooled their economies to serve the US’ needs have been rendered disproportionately uncompetitive. The tariffs on them are higher. They would falsely appear less efficient than other economies that have spent decades failing to produce things Americans want at prices they would pay.
Let us look at a specific example: Bangladesh and India. The former has long been dependent on the export of clothing to the West. Since a tragic fire in one of its factories a decade ago, it has worked hard to upgrade labor standards; its hundreds of efficient textile mills have painstakingly learned how to produce clothes that fit any given quarter’s trends, are of acceptable quality and cost less than if they were made anywhere else.
Therefore, Americans buy more Bangladeshi-made clothes than from Indian factories. India’s sector is relatively inefficient, with smaller factories that cannot fulfill large orders and have fewer experienced workers.
The world has been turned upside down: Thanks to their failure to attract US buyers, Indian-made garments would be tariffed at 26 percent — 11 percentage points lower than the Trump tariff on Bangladesh, at 37 percent. In this industry, a couple of percentage points of margin are sufficient for contracts to shift. With an 11-point buffer, inefficient Indian garment factories should now outcompete Bangladesh — and Vietnam and Cambodia — without even trying. That is great news for Indians — and exactly the sort of mad irrationality that many policymakers in New Delhi were hoping for from the new “Washington consensus.”
Indian-made garments might now be cheaper than those from Bangladesh, but US-based factories are still uncompetitive with both of them. The cost difference in bulk orders between India and Bangladesh might be 10 percent, an unbridgeable chasm in this business. However, the cost difference between Bangladesh and the US is an order of magnitude greater. US-based shirts can be two or three times as expensive to produce.
Forget about fairness for a moment. Yes, Vietnam might have taken a generations-long bet on friendship and integration with a country that was within living memory bombing its villages. And yes, that bet might have been shown, in the course of a single afternoon, to be a grave national mistake. Nobody in the White House would care about that.
Trump has deliberately targeted his own voters with those tariffs. A flat duty would reduce consumer welfare, raising prices for everyone. However, it would have, for a while, retained the supply chains developed over decades to serve the US.
And if you believe, like Trump, in a manufacturing renaissance behind tariff walls, a flat tariff is the only thing that could work. A constant duty of 20 percent would give a clear target for possible investors in US garments: Get bulk costs to within 20 percent of Bangladesh and you are set. And until the moment US manufacturing hits that target and begins substituting the most efficient foreign producer, Americans would continue to benefit from that country’s existing competence and expertise.
Instead, those proportional — not reciprocal — tariffs would ensure that US consumers are deliberately forced to buy inferior goods from abroad, not just more expensive ones. Poorer quality, pricier goods from India or Colombia (10 percent tariffs, 27 percentage points lower than Bangladesh) would suddenly turn up in US shops.
No jobs would be created. Even under optimistic scenarios, investment cannot crowd back into US garment factories now. Trump has ensured that the price target that new US manufacturing must now hit to make a profit has become high and unpredictable. Gone is the simple ask: Beat Bangladesh’s cost plus tariffs, since the market has proved they do T-shirts best, and so if you beat them, you beat everyone.
If Bangladesh faces a higher unit cost than all its competitors, investors cannot rely on the historical wisdom of the market. Instead, they now need to imagine exactly how much hypothetical Indian-made T-shirts, currently priced out by Bangladeshi factories, would cost if production shifted there from Bangladesh. They would have to repeat that for every possible competitor and revisit it every year depending on which country attracts productivity-enhancing investment in the post-proportional tariff world.
If that sounds like a nightmare, you are not wrong. In fact, the Trump tariffs are designed to maximize uncertainty. Many hoped that they would constitute a single hit to prices, and any inflationary bump would be “transitory.” However, that tariff formula almost guarantees that uncertainty is ongoing and inflation would be sustained.
That is because those trade restrictions do not just fight economic theory, they are designed to battle 20 years of cumulative market wisdom — the wisdom that decided not just that Vietnam was cheaper than the US, but also that it was more efficient than Indonesia. For his voters, Trump’s tariffs have unleashed the worst of all possible worlds.
Mihir Sharma is a Bloomberg Opinion columnist. A senior fellow at the Observer Research Foundation in New Delhi, he is author of Restart: The Last Chance for the Indian Economy.
The gutting of Voice of America (VOA) and Radio Free Asia (RFA) by US President Donald Trump’s administration poses a serious threat to the global voice of freedom, particularly for those living under authoritarian regimes such as China. The US — hailed as the model of liberal democracy — has the moral responsibility to uphold the values it champions. In undermining these institutions, the US risks diminishing its “soft power,” a pivotal pillar of its global influence. VOA Tibetan and RFA Tibetan played an enormous role in promoting the strong image of the US in and outside Tibet. On VOA Tibetan,
Sung Chien-liang (宋建樑), the leader of the Chinese Nationalist Party’s (KMT) efforts to recall Democratic Progressive Party (DPP) Legislator Lee Kun-cheng (李坤城), caused a national outrage and drew diplomatic condemnation on Tuesday after he arrived at the New Taipei City District Prosecutors’ Office dressed in a Nazi uniform. Sung performed a Nazi salute and carried a copy of Adolf Hitler’s Mein Kampf as he arrived to be questioned over allegations of signature forgery in the recall petition. The KMT’s response to the incident has shown a striking lack of contrition and decency. Rather than apologizing and distancing itself from Sung’s actions,
US President Trump weighed into the state of America’s semiconductor manufacturing when he declared, “They [Taiwan] stole it from us. They took it from us, and I don’t blame them. I give them credit.” At a prior White House event President Trump hosted TSMC chairman C.C. Wei (魏哲家), head of the world’s largest and most advanced chip manufacturer, to announce a commitment to invest US$100 billion in America. The president then shifted his previously critical rhetoric on Taiwan and put off tariffs on its chips. Now we learn that the Trump Administration is conducting a “trade investigation” on semiconductors which
By now, most of Taiwan has heard Taipei Mayor Chiang Wan-an’s (蔣萬安) threats to initiate a vote of no confidence against the Cabinet. His rationale is that the Democratic Progressive Party (DPP)-led government’s investigation into alleged signature forgery in the Chinese Nationalist Party’s (KMT) recall campaign constitutes “political persecution.” I sincerely hope he goes through with it. The opposition currently holds a majority in the Legislative Yuan, so the initiation of a no-confidence motion and its passage should be entirely within reach. If Chiang truly believes that the government is overreaching, abusing its power and targeting political opponents — then