On one level, the UK’s departure from the EU was an unintended consequence of a too-clever political ploy by former British prime minister David Cameron.
In 2015, to undercut the appeal of then-UK Independence Party leader Nigel Farage and secure a Conservative majority in the upcoming British general election, Cameron promised a referendum on whether the UK should stay in the EU.
Cameron expected to win and keep the UK in the bloc. He succeeded in his first aim, only to resign immediately when the “Leave” side won the 2016 referendum on the Britain’s EU membership.
Illustration: Mountain People
Brexit, on this view, was simply a historical accident, the result of one politician’s tactical miscalculation, but this is a superficial rendering of a complex story.
When the German philosopher Georg Wilhelm Friedrich Hegel wrote that “the owl of Minerva spreads its wings only with the coming of the dusk,” he meant that the direction of history is evident only after the event. It was a colorful way of stating the law of unintended consequences.
The consequences of Cameron’s political maneuvers were unintended, but his political passions were doing the work of Hegel’s weltgeist, or world spirit — the unseen force driving history.
This argument suggests that Brexit was in some sense predetermined. To be sure, no one engaging in the debate at the time thought so. Both “Leavers” and “Remainers” believed that the outcome was open and fought hard to ensure the result they wanted.
In retrospect, there was a whiff of inevitability about the UK’s separation — not from Europe, but from the EU as the institutional expression of it. To be fanciful, one could say that the Leavers instinctively sensed that dusk was approaching, whereas the Remainers did not.
After all, the UK joined the EU late and was an awkward member, and the weight of its past increasingly militated against the bloc’s future. Looking back, the rupture began with the UK’s decision to opt out of the Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) established by the 1992 Maastricht Treaty.
The EMU, which every EU member state was expected to join, was intended to be a stepping-stone to political union. EU leaders saw the 2012 to 2014 eurozone crisis, caused by the European single currency’s lack of political counterparts, as the necessary spur, or goad, to further statebuilding.
Since that crisis, the EU has taken tentative steps toward a fiscal union, banking union and a lender-of-last-resort function for the European Central Bank (ECB), and, although still mostly on paper, to strengthen the supervisory and surveillance powers of the European Commission, European Parliament and ECB.
The economic crisis caused by the COVID-19 pandemic has resulted in an ambitious fiscal rescue plan. So, the Leavers were right to see a federalist logic embedded in the EU’s economic structure.
However, is federalism really Europe’s destiny? Many federalists argue that if the EU’s 27 members do not advance all the way to a political union, Europe would retreat all the way to a congeries of nation-states.
Yet, such a binary choice is surely false. There are several possible versions of Europe. One alternative is what former German minister of finance Wolfgang Schauble called a Europe of “variable geometry”: A core group of member states headed by Germany would federalize sufficiently to make the single-currency system work, while a Mediterranean group would choose more flexible arrangements, such as adjustable exchange rates.
This path is feasible and logical. It has not been followed because, rather unattractively, it harks back — possibly unconsciously — to the old idea that Europe is inherently divided into productive and unproductive parts, and “races.” However, it remains a possibility.
A more seductive vision is that of a modernized medievalism.
Adrian Pabst, a political science professor at the University of Kent, approvingly describes today’s European system as consisting of “hybrid institutions, overlapping jurisdictions, multiple membership, polycentric authority and multilevel governance.”
This Europe is grounded not in legal contracts, but in the reality of social relationships.
Loyalty flows from proximity, not passports, and “mutualization” is the motive and method for undertaking common tasks. This Europe takes seriously ideas such as subsidiarity and the tragedy of the commons. Its vision is that of a civil society able to undertake all the necessary tasks of economic management without the central controls federalists deem essential.
Immediately after World War II, the idea of a decentralized Europe offered an attractive middle way between the destructive poles of a Hitlerian empire and warring nation-states. It had a particular, and obvious, appeal in Germany itself, where a federal republic was established on the basis of a weak federalism.
British economist John Maynard Keynes, too, was attracted by the idea of combining “small political and cultural units ... into larger, and more or less closely knit, economic units.”
Had Europe evolved along these lines, the UK might have been less estranged from the EU, because the bloc itself would have been a different animal.
However, in Pabst’s telling, the European idea succumbed to the instrumental “neo-functionalism” of statebuilders like French entrepreneur Jean Monnet and the “ordo-liberalism” of British economist Friedrich Hayek, who wanted a market order based on rules rather than norms.
It is a moot point whether the vision of a modernized feudalism has any part to play in the future. For one thing, it lacks a sharp analytical edge, which is very important to win academic advocacy of an idea. Social scientists can think in terms of state, market and society, and divide their work into political science, economics and sociology, but a scheme of social thought that dulls academic boundaries leaves them floundering outside their disciplines like beached whales.
Moreover, although feudal Europe was extremely vibrant religiously and culturally, it was economically static. The city-states of the Renaissance, forerunners of modernity, produced wonders of thought and art, but little technological progress, productivity growth or increases in per capita income. It fell to the newly unified nation-states of northwestern Europe to achieve economic takeoff.
The primary requirement of today’s democracies is to devise a successful combination of localism and the centralized control needed for sustained economic growth and tolerable equality of conditions.
Perhaps there is a way Europe can do it. What Brexit shows is that we have not yet found it.
Robert Skidelsky, professor emeritus of political economy at Warwick University and a fellow of the British Academy in history and economics, is a member of the British House of Lords.
Copyright: Project Syndicate
A high-school student surnamed Yang (楊) gained admissions to several prestigious medical schools recently. However, when Yang shared his “learning portfolio” on social media, he was caught exaggerating and even falsifying content, and his admissions were revoked. Now he has to take the “advanced subjects test” scheduled for next month. With his outstanding performance in the general scholastic ability test (GSAT), Yang successfully gained admissions to five prestigious medical schools. However, his university dreams have now been frustrated by the “flaws” in his learning portfolio. This is a wake-up call not only for students, but also teachers. Yang did make a big
As former president Ma Ying-jeou (馬英九) concludes his fourth visit to China since leaving office, Taiwan finds itself once again trapped in a familiar cycle of political theater. The Democratic Progressive Party (DPP) has criticized Ma’s participation in the Straits Forum as “dancing with Beijing,” while the Chinese Nationalist Party (KMT) defends it as an act of constitutional diplomacy. Both sides miss a crucial point: The real question is not whether Ma’s visit helps or hurts Taiwan — it is why Taiwan lacks a sophisticated, multi-track approach to one of the most complex geopolitical relationships in the world. The disagreement reduces Taiwan’s
Former president Ma Ying-jeou (馬英九) is visiting China, where he is addressed in a few ways, but never as a former president. On Sunday, he attended the Straits Forum in Xiamen, not as a former president of Taiwan, but as a former Chinese Nationalist Party (KMT) chairman. There, he met with Chinese People’s Political Consultative Conference Chairman Wang Huning (王滬寧). Presumably, Wang at least would have been aware that Ma had once been president, and yet he did not mention that fact, referring to him only as “Mr Ma Ying-jeou.” Perhaps the apparent oversight was not intended to convey a lack of
Chinese Nationalist Party (KMT) Chairman Eric Chu (朱立倫) last week announced that the KMT was launching “Operation Patriot” in response to an unprecedented massive campaign to recall 31 KMT legislators. However, his action has also raised questions and doubts: Are these so-called “patriots” pledging allegiance to the country or to the party? While all KMT-proposed campaigns to recall Democratic Progressive Party (DPP) lawmakers have failed, and a growing number of local KMT chapter personnel have been indicted for allegedly forging petition signatures, media reports said that at least 26 recall motions against KMT legislators have passed the second signature threshold