Lockdowns have brought most of the world’s advanced economies to a near standstill as policymakers fight the coronavirus pandemic by banning all but essential movement outside the home.
Tens of millions of employees across retail, entertainment, food services, personal services, professional services, education and other heavily affected sectors have already been put on short time, furloughed or let go.
Small businesses and the self-employed are among the worst affected groups, but the loss of output, income and jobs is spreading all along the supply chain to businesses of all sizes.
Lockdowns have successfully disrupted the transmission of the coronavirus and show some signs of reducing the number of reported new cases and deaths.
Yet the high economic and social cost is fueling demands for governments to articulate a clear exit strategy that would allow the economy to restart.
Policymakers and their science advisers, as well as businesses and voters, must weigh the relationship between the health benefits and economic costs of lockdowns.
“We cannot let the cure be much worse than the problem itself,” US President Donald Trump wrote on Twitter on March 23.
However, some economists have pushed back, saying that there is no trade-off between fighting the pandemic and minimizing the economic fallout.
In their view, lockdowns actually reduce deaths and the economic damage compared with an uncontrolled epidemic by reducing the duration and severity of the crisis.
For proponents, lockdowns are a policy intervention that has zero opportunity cost and actually improves outcomes in all dimensions compared with an uncontrolled epidemic.
The claim that lockdowns have health and economic benefits has been most forcefully made in a paper published by three researchers from the US Federal Reserve System and the Massachusetts Institute of Technology.
“Pandemics Depress the Economy, Public Health Interventions Do Not: Evidence from the 1918 Flu,” was published by Sergio Correia, Stephan Luck and Emil Verner on March 26.
“We find that cities that intervened earlier and more aggressively do not perform worse and, if anything, grow faster after the pandemic is over,” they said. “Our findings thus indicate that NPIs [non-pharmaceutical interventions] not only lower mortality; they also mitigate the adverse economic consequences of a pandemic.”
Even without a lockdown, severe epidemics cause lots of economic disruption through deaths, absences from work, and as individuals and households adopt their own voluntary social distancing measures.
If NPIs can reduce the duration and severity of the epidemic, it might be possible to reduce the economic costs, as well as cut the number of deaths.
Correia, Luck and Verner said that NPIs can improve health and economic outcomes based on the experience of the influenza pandemic in the US in 1918 and 1919.
“Our analysis yields two main insights. First, we find that areas that were more severely affected by the 1918 Flu Pandemic see a sharp and persistent decline in real economic activity,” they said.
“Second, we find that early and extensive NPIs have no adverse effect on local economic outcomes. On the contrary, cities that intervened earlier and more aggressively experience a relative increase in real economic activity after the pandemic,” they said.
“Altogether, our findings suggest that pandemics can have substantial economic costs, and NPIs can have economic merits, beyond lowering mortality,” they said.
For their evidence about NPIs, Correia, Luck and Verner relied on an earlier data set of restrictions introduced by 43 cities during the influenza pandemic.
“Nonpharmaceutical Interventions Implemented by US Cities During the 1918-1919 Influenza Pandemic,” was published by Howard Markel, Harvey Lipman and Alexander Navarro, as well as others, in 2007.
The NPIs cataloged in the earlier paper were mostly school closures, public gathering bans, and legally mandated isolation and quarantine.
Yet it also considered other measures, including altering work schedules, limited closure or regulations of businesses, transportation restrictions, public risk communications and mask ordinances.
Correia, Luck and Verner correlated the speed with which these measures were enforced and the length they were maintained with four health and economic outcomes.
They looked at death rates, manufacturing output and employment, bank assets and loan charge offs, and motor vehicle ownership at city or state level.
Death rates were taken from the annual “Mortality Statistics of the United States”; manufacturing and vehicle ownership from the annual “Statistical Abstract of the United States” for 1909, 1914, 1919, 1921 and 1923; and bank assets and charge offs from the “Annual Reports of the Comptroller of the Currency.”
One key limitation is the low frequency of many of these data sources, nearly all of which present annual statistics rather than monthly statistics, which makes it harder to identify short-term effects.
Unfortunately for economic historians, the influenza pandemic occurred right at the start, or just before, the big expansion in federal statistics collection between World War I and World War II.
The newly created Federal Reserve System, for example, only started publishing monthly estimates for industrial production from 1919 (“Celebrating 100 Years of the Industrial Production Index,” US Federal Reserve, Jan. 18, 2019).
There are several reasons to be cautious about relying on the correlations in the Correia, Luck and Verner paper about influenza in 1918 to draw conclusions about the economic impact of coronavirus lockdowns now.
First, the influenza pandemic coincided with the end of the war and the transition from a wartime to a peacetime economy, a point the authors acknowledge, but only briefly and without much further analysis.
Disentangling the economic effects of the pandemic from post-war demobilization has proved notoriously hard for economic historians.
Second, restrictions introduced in 1918, mostly school closures, mass gathering bans and isolation/quarantine, were much less severe than the travel bans introduced as part of the lockdowns this year.
For the most part, the NPIs employed in 1918 were far less disruptive for business activity, and the most severe of those restrictions were often enforced for relatively short periods.
Third, the lack of high-frequency monthly data makes it much more difficult to assess the short-term economic effect of the NPIs in 1918.
In theory, the longer-term impact of NPIs can be tracked in the annual data, but comparisons across the war years (1919 with 1914) or over a period of rapid economic change (1923 with 1919) are fraught with difficulty.
The authors make some effort to control for cross-state differences in economic structure — for example the share of agriculture and manufacturing in the state economy — but this was a period of very rapid change.
Correia, Luck and Verner have made the best of the very limited data that is available on economic dynamics in 1918 and 1919, and it is an impressive study, but their conclusions rest on very fragile data foundations.
The limited available data cannot convincingly support their relatively bold conclusions and policy recommendations about the economic effect of epidemic controls.
In any event, the local non-pharmaceutical interventions employed in 1918 were very different from and more modest than the whole-economy lockdowns being employed now.
Policymakers should be wary of concluding that there is no trade off between lockdowns to save lives and the effect on the economy.
John Kemp is a Reuters market analyst. The views expressed are his own.
The EU’s biggest banks have spent years quietly creating a new way to pay that could finally allow customers to ditch their Visa Inc and Mastercard Inc cards — the latest sign that the region is looking to dislodge two of the most valuable financial firms on the planet. Wero, as the project is known, is now rolling out across much of western Europe. Backed by 16 major banks and payment processors including BNP Paribas SA, Deutsche Bank AG and Worldline SA, the platform would eventually allow a German customer to instantly settle up with, say, a hotel in France
On August 6, Ukraine crossed its northeastern border and invaded the Russian region of Kursk. After spending more than two years seeking to oust Russian forces from its own territory, Kiev turned the tables on Moscow. Vladimir Putin seemed thrown off guard. In a televised meeting about the incursion, Putin came across as patently not in control of events. The reasons for the Ukrainian offensive remain unclear. It could be an attempt to wear away at the morale of both Russia’s military and its populace, and to boost morale in Ukraine; to undermine popular and elite confidence in Putin’s rule; to
A traffic accident in Taichung — a city bus on Sept. 22 hit two Tunghai University students on a pedestrian crossing, killing one and injuring the other — has once again brought up the issue of Taiwan being a “living hell for pedestrians” and large vehicle safety to public attention. A deadly traffic accident in Taichung on Dec. 27, 2022, when a city bus hit a foreign national, his Taiwanese wife and their one-year-old son in a stroller on a pedestrian crossing, killing the wife and son, had shocked the public, leading to discussions and traffic law amendments. However, just after the
The international community was shocked when Israel was accused of launching an attack on Lebanon by rigging pagers to explode. Most media reports in Taiwan focused on whether the pagers were produced locally, arousing public concern. However, Taiwanese should also look at the matter from a security and national defense perspective. Lebanon has eschewed technology, partly because of concerns that countries would penetrate its telecommunications networks to steal confidential information or launch cyberattacks. It has largely abandoned smartphones and modern telecommunications systems, replacing them with older and relatively basic communications equipment. However, the incident shows that using older technology alone cannot