One of the biggest economic surprises of last year was that the stunning drop in international oil prices did not deliver a larger boost to international growth. Despite the collapse in prices, from more than US$115 per barrel in June 2014 to US$45 at the end of November last year, most macroeconomic models suggest that the impact on international growth has been less than expected — perhaps 0.5 percent of international GDP.
The good news is that this welcome, but modest, effect on growth is unlikely to die out this year. The bad news is that low prices are likely to place even greater strains on the main oil-exporting nations.
The recent decline in oil prices is on par with the supply-driven drop in 1985 to 1986, when OPEC members decided to reverse supply cuts to regain market share. It is also comparable to the demand-driven collapse in 2008 to 2009, following the global financial crisis. To the extent that demand factors drive an oil-price drop, one would not expect a major positive impact; the oil price is more of an automatic stabilizer than an exogenous force driving the international economy. Supply shocks, on the other hand, ought to have a significant positive impact.
Although parsing the oil-price shock of 2014 to last year is not as straightforward as in the two previous episodes, the driving forces seem to be roughly evenly split between demand and supply factors. Certainly, a slowing China that is rebalancing toward domestic consumption has put a damper on all international commodity prices, with metal indices also falling sharply last year. (Gold prices, for example, at US$1,050 per ounce at the end of November, are far off their peak of nearly US$1,890 in September 2011, and copper prices have fallen almost as much since 2011).
However, new sources of oil supply have been at least as important. Thanks to the shale-energy revolution, US oil production has risen from five million barrels per day in 2008 to 9.3 million barrels last year, a supply boom that has so far persisted, despite the price collapse. Anticipation of post-sanctions Iranian oil production has also affected markets.
A decline in oil prices is to some extent a zero-sum game, with producers losing and consumers gaining. The usual thinking is that lower prices stimulate international demand, because consumers are likely to spend most of the windfall, whereas producers typically adjust by cutting back savings.
Last year, though, this behavioral difference has been less pronounced than usual. One reason is that emerging-market energy importers have a much larger international economic footprint than they did in the 1980s and their approach to oil markets is much more interventionist than in the advanced nations.
Nations such as India and China stabilize retail energy markets through government-financed subsidies to keep prices down for consumers. The costs of these subsidies had become quite massive as oil prices peaked and many nations were already looking hard for ways to cut back. Thus, as oil prices have fallen, emerging-market governments have taken advantage of the opportunity to reduce the fiscal subsidies.
At the same time, many oil exporters are being forced to scale back expenditure plans in the face of sharply falling revenues. Even Saudi Arabia, despite its vast oil and financial reserves, has come under strain, owing to a rapidly rising population and increased military spending associated with conflicts in the Middle East.
The muted effect of oil prices on international growth should not have come as a complete surprise. Academic research has been pointing in this direction for a long time. Oil is now thought to be less of an independent driver of business cycles than was previously believed. Also restraining growth is a sharp decline in energy-related investment. After years of rapid growth, international investment in oil production and exploration fell by US$150 billion dollars last year. Eventually, this is likely to feed back into prices, but only slowly and gradually: Futures markets have oil prices rising to US$60 per barrel only by 2020.
The good news for this year is that most macroeconomic models suggest that the impact of lower oil prices on growth tends to stretch out for a couple years. Thus, low prices should continue to support growth, even if emerging-market importers continue to use the savings to cut subsidies.
For oil producers, though, the risks are rising. Only a couple — notably governance-challenged Venezuela — are in outright collapse; but many are teetering on the brink of recession. Nations with floating exchange rates, including Colombia, Mexico and Russia, have managed to adjust so far, despite facing significantly tighter fiscal constraints (though Russia’s situation remains especially vulnerable if low oil prices endure). By contrast, nations with rigid exchange-rate regimes are being tested more severely. Saudi Arabia’s long-standing peg to the US dollar, once apparently invulnerable, has come under enormous pressure in recent weeks.
In short, oil prices were not quite as consequential for international growth last year as seemed likely at the beginning of last year. And strong reserve positions and relatively conservative macroeconomic policies have enabled most major producers to weather enormous fiscal stress so far, without falling into crisis; but this year could be different, and not in a good way — especially for producers.
Kenneth Rogoff, a professor of economics and public policy at Harvard University and recipient of the 2011 Deutsche Bank Prize in Financial Economics, was the chief economist of the IMF from 2001 to 2003.
Copyright:Project syndicate
In an article published in Newsweek on Monday last week, President William Lai (賴清德) challenged China to retake territories it lost to Russia in the 19th century rather than invade Taiwan. “If it is really for the sake of territorial integrity, why doesn’t China take back Russia?” Lai asked, referring to territories lost in 1858 and 1860. The territories once made up the two flanks of northern Manchuria. Once ceded to Russia, they became part of the Russian far east. Claims since then have been made that China and Russia settled the disputes in the 1990s through the 2000s and that “China
China has successfully held its Forum on China-Africa Cooperation, with 53 of 55 countries from the African Union (AU) participating. The two countries that did not participate were Eswatini and the Sahrawi Arab Democratic Republic, which have no diplomatic relations with China. Twenty-four leaders were reported to have participated. Despite African countries complaining about summit fatigue, with recent summits held with Russia, Italy, South Korea, the US and Indonesia, as well as Japan next month, they still turned up in large numbers in Beijing. China’s ability to attract most of the African leaders to a summit demonstrates that it is still being
Trips to the Kenting Peninsula in Pingtung County have dredged up a lot of public debate and furor, with many complaints about how expensive and unreasonable lodging is. Some people even call it a tourist “butchering ground.” Many local business owners stake claims to beach areas by setting up parasols and driving away people who do not rent them. The managing authority for the area — Kenting National Park — has long ignored the issue. Ultimately, this has affected the willingness of domestic travelers to go there, causing tourist numbers to plummet. In 2008, Taiwan opened the door to Chinese tourists and in
Taiwan People’s Party (TPP) Chairman Ko Wen-je (柯文哲) on Thursday was handcuffed and escorted by police to the Taipei Detention Center, after the Taipei District Court ordered that he be detained and held incommunicado for suspected corruption during his tenure as Taipei mayor. The ruling reversed an earlier decision by the same court on Monday last week that ordered Ko’s release without bail. That decision was appealed by prosecutors on Wednesday, leading the High Court to conclude that Ko had been “actively involved” in the alleged corruption and it ordered the district court to hold a second detention hearing. Video clips