When policymakers turn to economists for guidance, they expect the advice they receive to be grounded in science, not academic factionalism or political presuppositions. After all, the policies they will be putting in place will have real implications for real people. Unfortunately, however, sound science is not always the driving force behind economic analysis and policy recommendations.
In a recent critique of what he calls the “mathiness” of modern economics, Paul Romer of New York University said that economists should take measures to exclude academic factionalism and politics from the “dismal science.” Romer grounds his case in an ongoing debate in his field about the role that ideas play in promoting economic growth.
Romer seems to be worried principally about some economists’ tendency to claim that what is true about certain types of theories is true of all theories and thus applicable to the real world. As an example of this tendency, Romer cites the work of University of Chicago economist Robert Lucas, who, in his 2009 paper Ideas and Growth, dismisses the role that books or blueprints can play in driving growth.
“Some knowledge can be ‘embodied’ in books, blueprints, machines and other kinds of physical capital, and we know how to introduce capital into a growth model, but we also know that doing so does not by itself provide an engine of sustained growth,” Lucas wrote.
The problem is that Lucas’ statement is true only for models of economic growth that are specified in such a way that the return on “embodied” capital drops to zero as capital accumulates.
As Romer acknowledges, there are many models for which this is simply not true.
What Lucas makes out to be a general truth — that the path to economic growth cannot lie in creating and acquiring the kind of knowledge that is “embodied” in books, blueprints and machines — rests on a barely examined decision to restrict attention to just a few kinds of models.
Lucas’ decision might be somewhat justifiable if the models he chose were the only ones that were correct. However, of course that is not the case.
In addition to criticizing those that draw general conclusions from specific cases, Romer takes aim at those who claim that economic models permit only one mode of interaction and only one mode of individual decisionmaking.
Romer’s principle objection is to the assumption that the only interaction allowable in economic growth models is what is known as “price-taking,” the buying or selling of goods and services at the price currently offered by the market.
I would add to that my objection to the assumption that individual decisionmaking is always characterized by rational expectations.
Assumptions like these might be adequate as foundations on which to build models to help us understand the world, but only if market processes were structured exactly right, smoothing out at the aggregate level all the deviations from price-taking and rational expectations that are clearly evident at the individual level. Asking whether, which and when market processes meet such criteria is an empirical question. Claiming that all market processes must be so structured is theoretical malfeasance.
And it is widespread. In the field of growth theory, Romer sees the current generation of neoclassical economists grind out paper after paper imposing the theoretical restrictions necessary for a price-taking equilibrium. As he correctly says, such papers are useless for any purpose other than advancing their authors’ positions in academic status games.
Meanwhile, in macroeconomics, economists, bankers, industrialists, technocrats and politicians make the claim that the policies governments could implement to speed an economic recovery must be, if not counterproductive, at least too risky. After all, that is what a model with a very restricted class of rational expectations would predict.
At the same time, stakeholders must recognize that the problem Romer pinpoints is not a new one. Just the other day, I came across critiques of expansionary fiscal and monetary policy made by Canadian economist Jacob Viner and French economist Etienne Mantoux. They both argued in the 1930s — in the middle of the Great Depression, no less — that government efforts to boost employment would always result in undesirable and unwarranted inflation, and would probably reduce output in the long run.
What is most depressing about Romer’s argument is how unlikely it is to be heeded. Romer might be able to convince academic economists to be more cautious about making claims concerning the generality of theories of economic growth. However, it is less than clear that bankers, industrialists, technocrats and politicians — who are responsible for the policies that impact people’s lives — will do the same.
J. Bradford DeLong is a professor of economics at the University of California at Berkeley and a research associate at the US’ National Bureau of Economic Research.
Copyright: Project Syndicate
US President Donald Trump last week told reporters that he had signed about 12 letters to US trading partners, which were set to be sent out yesterday, levying unilateral tariff rates of up to 70 percent from Aug. 1. However, Trump did not say which countries the letters would be sent to, nor did he discuss the specific tariff rates, reports said. The news of the tariff letters came as Washington and Hanoi reached a trade deal earlier last week to cut tariffs on Vietnamese exports to the US to 20 percent from 46 percent, making it the first Asian country
On Monday, Minister of Foreign Affairs Lin Chia-lung (林佳龍) delivered a welcome speech at the ILA-ASIL Asia-Pacific Research Forum, addressing more than 50 international law experts from more than 20 countries. With an aim to refute the People’s Republic of China’s (PRC) claim to be the successor to the 1945 Chinese government and its assertion that China acquired sovereignty over Taiwan, Lin articulated three key legal positions in his speech: First, the Cairo Declaration and Potsdam Declaration were not legally binding instruments and thus had no legal effect for territorial disposition. All determinations must be based on the San Francisco Peace
As things heated up in the Middle East in early June, some in the Pentagon resisted American involvement in the Israel-Iran war because it would divert American attention and resources from the real challenge: China. This was exactly wrong. Rather, bombing Iran was the best thing that could have happened for America’s Asia policy. When it came to dealing with the Iranian nuclear program, “all options are on the table” had become an American mantra over the past two decades. But the more often US administration officials insisted that military force was in the cards, the less anyone believed it. After
During an impromptu Taiwan People’s Party (TPP) rally on Tuesday last week to protest what the party called the unfairness of the judicial system, a young TPP supporter said that if Taiwan goes to war, he would “surrender to the [Chinese] People’s Liberation Army [PLA] with unyielding determination.” The rally was held after former Taipei deputy mayor Pong Cheng-sheng’s (彭振聲) wife took her life prior to Pong’s appearance in court to testify in the Core Pacific corruption case involving former Taipei mayor and TPP chairman Ko Wen-je (柯文哲). The TPP supporter said President William Lai (賴清德) was leading them to die on