The Directorate-General of Budget, Accounting and Statistics (DGBAS) on May 24 forecast that Taiwan’s GDP is set to grow by 2.4 percent this year, a drop of more than 1 percentage point adjustment from its February forecast. This was a major cut and it now seems that economic growth is unlikely to exceed 3 percent this year. Following the publication of the forecast, the government attracted widespread criticism, leading Premier Jiang Yi-huah (江宜樺) to announce a set of measures aimed at stimulating the lackluster economy.
The agency’s numerous forecast adjustments have made people question its abilities. However, adjustments to economic forecasts are standard practice. A comparison between the agency’s February forecast and its most recent one indicates that the driver for the downward adjustment was that export shipments for the first quarter of the year were lower than expected.
Taiwan’s economy is small and open, and fluctuations in the global economy can have a great impact on it. The global economy is affected by many factors and its performance is very difficult to forecast. Although the agency’s February forecast may have been slightly more optimistic than forecasts from other institutions, its recent downward adjustment was still reasonable.
Given current knowledge, economists still have a long way to go before they are able to deliver more precise forecasts. If those in charge of DGBAS were able to reliably forecast economic activity, they would have been picked up by overseas financial institutions long ago. Instead, the real problem is how economic forecasts should be considered, and whether they require direct responses.
Since economic forecasts are often not reliable, the government should not respond directly to them. According to media reports, the Cabinet immediately reacted to the DGBAS latest forecast by proposing measures to stimulate the economy. A closer look at these measures shows that most of them were already planned or in the process of being implemented, and their implementation was simply accelerated.
The announced NT$3.24 billion (US$108.2 million) investment is but a drop in the ocean in terms of the overall economy. Most of the announced measures are politically, not economically, motivated, and are largely symbolic.
Government policy should not be a direct response to such forecasts. If these hastily formulated measures were to have a substantive effect, the economy could perform even worse: Massive rushed investments would only lead to waste and misallocation of resources, and there is a risk that it could increase collusion between government and industry, benefiting the wealthy at the expense of the less well-off. This would do more harm than good to the nation.
After a prolonged slump, the economy is experiencing long-term structural problems that cannot be resolved by short-term stimulus measures. For ideological reasons and because of the composition of its supporter base, the Chinese Nationalist Party (KMT) is constantly advocating closer ties with China. It does little to promote other forms of foreign investment to diversify risk, and nor does it encourage effective measures to upgrade industry and keep businesses in Taiwan.
The long-term result of this approach has been a cross-strait factor price-equalization that has caused real wages in Taiwan to stagnate.
Additionally, since President Ma Ying-jeou (馬英九) came to power, government policies have facilitated housing speculation, leading to high property prices that restrict the spending of workers and concentrates capital in an unproductive sector. The result is anaemic domestic demand.
Over the past few years, the government has tried to increase domestic demand while economic growth has been restricted by fluctuations in the global economy. However, to be able to stimulate domestic spending through government policy it is also necessary to effect increases in real salaries and to bring speculation in the housing market under control.
Regrettably, to be able to deal with these issues, it is necessary to touch on the interests of the KMT’s core supporters and that would hurt donations to the party. Since the problem goes deep, addressing it will be a painful experience. Further, since Ma lacks the courage, every Cabinet measure aimed at stimulating the economy will be perfunctory at best.
For policy implementation to have a tangible effect it is not necessary to focus on GDP growth. Rather than being concerned about a few tenths of a percent, it would be far better to improve income distribution and social security guarantees which would allow the public to maintain a reasonable standard of living in the face of the international economic slump.
In the past, the KMT always boasted that it was adept at handling the economy and had promoted a set of values focused on economic growth. Now that it has to deal with economic stagnation resulting from structural problems, it cannot stop the public from using economic growth as the only standard by which to measure political achievement.
Therefore, when performance is poor, Cabinet members with responsibility for economic and financial matters end up being scapegoats for Ma.
Sher Chien-yuan is an assistant professor of business management at National Sun Yat-sen University. Liu Yu-hsi is a candidate for a doctoral degree in economics at Suffolk University, Boston, Massachusetts.
Translated by Perry Svensson
As strategic tensions escalate across the vast Indo-Pacific region, Taiwan has emerged as more than a potential flashpoint. It is the fulcrum upon which the credibility of the evolving American-led strategy of integrated deterrence now rests. How the US and regional powers like Japan respond to Taiwan’s defense, and how credible the deterrent against Chinese aggression proves to be, will profoundly shape the Indo-Pacific security architecture for years to come. A successful defense of Taiwan through strengthened deterrence in the Indo-Pacific would enhance the credibility of the US-led alliance system and underpin America’s global preeminence, while a failure of integrated deterrence would
The Executive Yuan recently revised a page of its Web site on ethnic groups in Taiwan, replacing the term “Han” (漢族) with “the rest of the population.” The page, which was updated on March 24, describes the composition of Taiwan’s registered households as indigenous (2.5 percent), foreign origin (1.2 percent) and the rest of the population (96.2 percent). The change was picked up by a social media user and amplified by local media, sparking heated discussion over the weekend. The pan-blue and pro-China camp called it a politically motivated desinicization attempt to obscure the Han Chinese ethnicity of most Taiwanese.
On Wednesday last week, the Rossiyskaya Gazeta published an article by Chinese President Xi Jinping (習近平) asserting the People’s Republic of China’s (PRC) territorial claim over Taiwan effective 1945, predicated upon instruments such as the 1943 Cairo Declaration and the 1945 Potsdam Proclamation. The article further contended that this de jure and de facto status was subsequently reaffirmed by UN General Assembly Resolution 2758 of 1971. The Ministry of Foreign Affairs promptly issued a statement categorically repudiating these assertions. In addition to the reasons put forward by the ministry, I believe that China’s assertions are open to questions in international
The Legislative Yuan passed an amendment on Friday last week to add four national holidays and make Workers’ Day a national holiday for all sectors — a move referred to as “four plus one.” The Chinese Nationalist Party (KMT) and the Taiwan People’s Party (TPP), who used their combined legislative majority to push the bill through its third reading, claim the holidays were chosen based on their inherent significance and social relevance. However, in passing the amendment, they have stuck to the traditional mindset of taking a holiday just for the sake of it, failing to make good use of