The king of Bhutan wants to make us all happier. Governments, he says, should aim to maximize their people’s Gross National Happiness, rather than their Gross National Product (GNP). Does this new emphasis on happiness represent a shift or just a passing fad?
It is easy to see why governments should de-emphasize economic growth when it is proving so elusive. The eurozone is not expected to grow at all this year. The British economy is contracting. Greece’s economy has been shrinking for years. Even China is expected to slow down. Why not give up growth and enjoy what we have?
No doubt this mood will pass when growth revives. Nevertheless, a deeper shift in attitude toward growth has occurred.
The first factor to undermine the pursuit of growth was concern about its sustainability. Can we continue growing at the old rate without endangering our future?
When people started talking about the “natural” limits to growth in the 1970s, they meant the impending exhaustion of food and non-renewable natural resources. Recently, the debate has shifted to carbon emissions. As the Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change of 2006 emphasized, we must sacrifice some growth today to ensure that we do not all fry tomorrow.
Curiously, the one taboo area in this discussion is population. The fewer people there are, the less risk we face of heating up the planet. However, instead of accepting the natural decline in their populations, rich-country governments absorb an increasing number of people to hold down wages and thereby grow faster.
A more recent concern focuses on the disappointing results of growth. It is increasingly understood that growth does not necessarily increase our sense of well-being. So why continue to grow?
The groundwork for this question was laid some time ago. In 1974, the economist Robert Easterlin published a famous paper, Does Economic Growth Improve the Human Lot? Some Empirical Evidence. After correlating per capita income and self-reported happiness levels across a number of countries, he reached a startling conclusion: probably not.
Above a low level of income, Easterlin found no correlation between happiness and GNP per head. In other words, GNP is a poor measure of life satisfaction.
That finding reinforced efforts to devise alternative indexes. In 1972, economists William Nordhaus and James Tobin formulated the “Net Economic Welfare” measure by deducting from GNP “bad” outputs, like pollution, and adding non-market activities like leisure. They showed that a society with more leisure and less work could have as much welfare as one with more work — and therefore more GNP — and less leisure.
Recent metrics have tried to incorporate a wider range of “quality of life” indicators. The trouble is that you can measure quantity of stuff, but not quality of life. How one combines quantity and quality in an index of “life satisfaction” is a matter of morals, not economics, so most economists stick to quantitative measures of “welfare.”
However, another finding has also started to influence the current debate on growth: Poor people within a country are less happy than rich people. Above a low level of sufficiency, happiness is determined much less by peoples’ absolute income than by their income relative to some reference group. We constantly compare our lot with that of others, feeling either superior or inferior, whatever our income level. Well-being depends more on how the fruits of growth are distributed than on their absolute amount.
Put another way, what matters for life satisfaction is the growth not of mean income, but of median income — the income of the typical person. Consider a population of 10 people (say, a factory) in which the managing director earns US$150,000 a year and the other nine, all workers, earn US$10,000 each. The mean average of their incomes is US$25,000, but 90 percent earn US$10,000. With this kind of income distribution, it would be surprising if growth increased the typical person’s sense of well-being.
That is not an idle example. In rich societies over the past three decades, mean incomes have been rising steadily, but typical incomes have been stagnating or even falling. In other words, a minority — a very small minority in countries like the US and Britain — has captured most of the gains of growth. In such cases, it is not more growth that we want, but more equality.
More equality would not only produce the contentment that flows from more security and better health, but also the satisfaction that flows from having more leisure, more time with family and friends, more respect from one’s fellows and more lifestyle choices. Great inequality makes us hungrier for goods than we would otherwise be, by reminding us that we have less than the next person. We live in a pushy society, with turbo-charged fathers and “tiger” mothers, constantly goading themselves and their children to “get ahead.”
The 19th-century philosopher John Stuart Mill had a more civilized view: “I confess I am not charmed with the ideal of life held out by those who think … that the trampling, crushing, elbowing, and treading on each other’s heels, which form the existing type of social life, are the most desirable lot of human kind … The best state for human nature is that in which, while no one is poor, no one desires to be richer, nor has any reason to fear being thrust back, by the efforts of others to push themselves forward.”
That lesson has been lost on most economists today, but not on the king of Bhutan — nor on the many people who recognize the limits of quantifiable wealth.
Robert Skidelsky, a member of the British House of Lords, is professor emeritus of political economy at Warwick University.
Copyright: Project Syndicate
Taiwan faces complex challenges like other Asia-Pacific nations, including demographic decline, income inequality and climate change. In fact, its challenges might be even more pressing. The nation struggles with rising income inequality, declining birthrates and soaring housing costs while simultaneously navigating intensifying global competition among major powers. To remain competitive in the global talent market, Taiwan has been working to create a more welcoming environment and legal framework for foreign professionals. One of the most significant steps in this direction was the enactment of the Act for the Recruitment and Employment of Foreign Professionals (外國專業人才延攬及僱用法) in 2018. Subsequent amendments in
The recent passing of Taiwanese actress Barbie Hsu (徐熙媛), known to many as “Big S,” due to influenza-induced pneumonia at just 48 years old is a devastating reminder that the flu is not just a seasonal nuisance — it is a serious and potentially fatal illness. Hsu, a beloved actress and cultural icon who shaped the memories of many growing up in Taiwan, should not have died from a preventable disease. Yet her death is part of a larger trend that Taiwan has ignored for too long — our collective underestimation of the flu and our low uptake of the
US President Donald Trump on Saturday signed orders to impose tariffs on Canada, Mexico and China effective from today. Trump decided to slap 25 percent tariffs on goods from Mexico and Canada as well as 10 percent on those coming from China, but would only impose a 10 percent tariff on Canadian energy products, including oil and electricity. Canada and Mexico on Sunday quickly responded with retaliatory tariffs against the US, while countermeasures from China are expected soon. Nevertheless, Trump announced yesterday to delay tariffs on Mexico and Canada for a month and said he would hold further talks with
Taiwan’s undersea cables connecting it to the world were allegedly severed several times by a Chinese ship registered under a flag of convenience. As the vessel sailed, it used several different automatic identification systems (AIS) to create fake routes. That type of “shadow fleet” and “gray zone” tactics could create a security crisis in Taiwan and warrants response measures. The concept of a shadow fleet originates from the research of Elisabeth Braw, senior fellow at the Washington-based Atlantic Council. The phenomenon was initiated by authoritarian countries such as Iran, North Korea and Russia, which have been hit by international economic