Abandoning a fixed exchange rate system was supposed to be a disaster, but Brazil pulled it off and Buenos Aires could have to if they hadn't held on as long as they did
The first glimpses of Argentina's recovery can be seen. To many, what happened, and what is happening there seems a mystery. Abandoning "convertibility," ie, a fixed exchange rate system, was supposed to be a disaster -- and it was. Output fell and unemployment increased dramatically. Fear of these costs, combined with IMF bailouts, kept Argentina from abandoning its currency board long after it was clear that the system could not be sustained. This stubbornness made matters worse when things finally fell apart.
But what primarily kept Argentines wedded to a system that could not work was fear of hyperinflation. The feared hyperinflation, so far, has not materialized. To be sure, there has been the normal inflation associated with large increases in import prices that always follow large devaluations, but rather than setting off a spiral of price increases, inflation rates appear to be dampening. Argentina seems set to join the long list of countries -- Brazil, Korea, Russia, Thailand, and Indonesia -- that managed devaluations without runaway inflation.
To an economist, Argentina's recovery is no surprise. Devaluation incites several restorative forces. Exports are cheaper, and revenues from exports (measured in pesos) are up dramatically. Tourism and related industries are booming. Import substitution takes place before your eyes: a clothing store that last year sold only imported apparel, now sells only domestically produced goods.
As in East Asia after its crisis of 1998, what inhibits these restorative forces is a lack of credit. Foreign ownership of banks was supposed to ensure their stability; it was expected that foreign banks would come to the rescue of their Argentine subsidiaries if they needed money. Deposits in the branches of American banks in Buenos Aires were to be as safe as deposits in Miami. Unfortunately, depositors learned otherwise.
On the other hand, foreign banks were always falling short in assuring an adequate supply of credit to small and medium sized Argentine firms. This lack of credit stifled growth, which contributed to the country's economic woes; and now credit has virtually dried up.
To be sure, some domestic banks continue to provide credit. But if the recovery is to be sustained credit must be expanded, either by creating new financial institutions or by expanding existing ones. Here credit cooperatives may be particularly important, given the seeming lack of confidence in the more traditional banking sector.
Revival of trade credit is also urgent -- its importance was recognized early on during East Asia's crisis, where Japan, in a good neighborly gesture, provided US$30 billion dollars through the Miyazawa initiative, much of which went to finance trade credit and help restart the economy.
The point is simple: Argentina's real resources, its people, with their enormous talents and skills, its fertile land, its capital goods remain. What the economy needs is reactivation, and government policies must focus on this task. If the private sector cannot improve the availability of credit on its own, and no good neighbor steps forward to help, as Japan did in East Asia, government must take a more active role in restructuring the existing credit institutions as well as creating new ones.
Directing credit in order to increase supply of goods need not be inflationary; on the contrary, the increased supply of domestically produced goods may be an effective instrument for combating inflation.
Appropriate accounting, separating expenditures for recapitalizing banks from ordinary expenditures, such as those needed to run hospitals and schools, would make clear that these expenditures are not by themselves inflationary. It is only the credit expansion that such expenditures allow which might be inflationary. In an economy with vast problems, underutilization of resources, and a massive lack of credit, a modest credit expansion would not in fact lead to high inflation.
Centering attention on reactivation makes clear why the focus on IMF credits is misguided. IMF credits will go to repay the IMF, not to reactivate the economy. Supposedly, the IMF credit will "restore confidence" in the economy, but whether it does so depends on the conditions that are imposed.
If the IMF imposes fiscal contraction or a misguided strategy for restructuring the financial sector (as it did in Indonesia), then the economy will be weakened and this will lead to a further erosion of confidence. If, on the other hand, IMF credit is obtained on reasonable terms, it will make a positive contribution. But it will be no panacea.
Indeed, IMF credit will do little to address the key economic issues, except to the extent that it frees up money from other international sources and those funds are used to reactivate the economy.
Where the international community can help Argentina is by opening its doors to Argentine goods, taking the rhetoric of free trade seriously and recognizing that trade can be an important instrument not only for long-term growth, but also for economic recovery. Exports will help reactivate the Argentine economy, while consumers in Europe and America will benefit from high quality goods at lower prices. This is one way of making globalization work to benefit those in need.
Joseph E. Stiglitz is Professor of Economics and Finance at Columbia University, the winner of the 2001 Nobel Prize in Economics, and author of "Globalization and its Discontents," published by W.W. Norton.
Copyright: Project Syndicate
As China steps up a campaign to diplomatically isolate and squeeze Taiwan, it has become more imperative than ever that Taipei play a greater role internationally with the support of the democratic world. To help safeguard its autonomous status, Taiwan needs to go beyond bolstering its defenses with weapons like anti-ship and anti-aircraft missiles. With the help of its international backers, it must also expand its diplomatic footprint globally. But are Taiwan’s foreign friends willing to translate their rhetoric into action by helping Taipei carve out more international space for itself? Beating back China’s effort to turn Taiwan into an international pariah
Typhoon Krathon made landfall in southwestern Taiwan last week, bringing strong winds, heavy rain and flooding, cutting power to more than 170,000 homes and water supply to more than 400,000 homes, and leading to more than 600 injuries and four deaths. Due to the typhoon, schools and offices across the nation were ordered to close for two to four days, stirring up familiar controversies over whether local governments’ decisions to call typhoon days were appropriate. The typhoon’s center made landfall in Kaohsiung’s Siaogang District (小港) at noon on Thursday, but it weakened into a tropical depression early on Friday, and its structure
Since the end of the Cold War, the US-China espionage battle has arguably become the largest on Earth. Spying on China is vital for the US, as China’s growing military and technological capabilities pose direct challenges to its interests, especially in defending Taiwan and maintaining security in the Indo-Pacific. Intelligence gathering helps the US counter Chinese aggression, stay ahead of threats and safeguard not only its own security, but also the stability of global trade routes. Unchecked Chinese expansion could destabilize the region and have far-reaching global consequences. In recent years, spying on China has become increasingly difficult for the US
Lately, China has been inviting Taiwanese influencers to travel to China’s Xinjiang region to make films, weaving a “beautiful Xinjiang” narrative as an antidote to the international community’s criticisms by creating a Potemkin village where nothing is awry. Such manipulations appear harmless — even compelling enough for people to go there — but peeling back the shiny veneer reveals something more insidious, something that is hard to ignore. These films are not only meant to promote tourism, but also harbor a deeper level of political intentions. Xinjiang — a region of China continuously listed in global human rights reports —