Tue, Jul 18, 2017 - Page 11 News List

Appraising Friedman, 50 years on

By Ferdinando Giugliano  /  Bloomberg

Paradigm shifts do not come often in economics. From Adam Smith to John Maynard Keynes, there is only a handful of academics who can claim to have radically changed the way we think about how markets should work and what governments can do to improve their functioning.

One such moment came almost 50 years ago when Milton Friedman delivered his presidential address to the American Economic Association in Washington.

The subject of the speech was the role that monetary policy can have in reducing unemployment and boosting growth. In Friedman’s view, central banks cannot reduce the long-run rate of unemployment at which an economy operates, or the “natural rate of unemployment.” Were the monetary authorities to stimulate demand then, they would only prompt workers to demand ever higher wages and cause inflation to accelerate.

It was a matter of only a few years before Friedman’s speech acquired a near-prophetic status.

In the 1970s, central banks tried to fight off the recession caused by oil shocks by slashing interest rates, but these policies only caused inflation to spiral out of control. This led to a major rethink of how monetary policy should work: Ever since, central banks have primarily sought to ensure that inflation remains low and stable, and have turned wary of stimulating the economy when they think it has hit the natural rate of unemployment. In this respect, Friedman’s thinking is alive and well today.

However, this does not mean that his 1967 presidential address has passed the test of time entirely.

Olivier Blanchard, the former IMF chief economist and a fellow at the Peterson Institute of International Economics, is reviewing the usefulness of the natural rate hypothesis — known as the “non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment” for a forthcoming publication.

His assessment, which was presented in Italy last week at the University of Naples Federico II, offers a thoughtful account of the various critiques which have been levied at Friedman, but does not refute a central implication of his address: that structural policies are needed to ensure more people can find work when the economy is running at full capacity.

Blanchard’s work clearly shows that downturns cause far more persistent scars than Friedman’s theory would suggest. His analysis of all the recessions that took place in 22 advanced economies over the past 50 years shows that, on average, the unemployment rate remains higher than it was during the boom well past the moment of the crisis.

This effect, which economists call “hysteresis,” is primarily the consequence of what occurs in the labor market after workers lose their jobs in a recession: The longer they remain unemployed, the higher the risk they become “disenfranchised,” either because they lose the necessary skills for companies to hire them or because they become discouraged and stop looking for a job.

This means that the “natural rate” is far less rigid than Friedman thought or made it seem.

The hysteresis hypothesis, which has been the subject of a multitude of studies in the past 30 years, has major implications for today’s central banks, especially in the US and the eurozone.

The US Federal Reserve has begun tightening monetary policy as the unemployment rate is now stable at about 4.5 percent, near what most economists would consider the “natural rate.” Yet labor force participation only stands at 62.8 percent, which might help to explain why wage growth remains subdued. Some economists, including Minneapolis Fed President Neel Kashkari, would like the Fed to pause raising rates, as there is scope for increasing employment without stoking inflation.

This story has been viewed 1205 times.

Comments will be moderated. Remarks containing abusive and obscene language, personal attacks of any kind or promotion will be removed and the user banned.

TOP top